03 Micro Walras

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    1/165

    1

    Part III:

    Walrasian Theory

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    2/165

    Literature

    Geoffrey A. Jehle, Philip J. Reny: Advanced

    Microeconomic Theory, 2nd Ed., PearsonInternational, 2001.

    2

    Hall R. Varian: Microeconomic Analysis, 3rdEd., W. W. Norton & Company, 1992.

    Andreu Mas-Colell, Micheal D. Whinston undJerry R. Green: Microeconomic Theory,Oxford University Press, 1995.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    3/165

    Overview

    1. Introduction

    2. Model

    3. Normative Analysis

    3

    Second Welfare Theorem

    4. Positive Analysis

    Existence Structural characteristics

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    4/165

    Introduction

    In Part II of this lecture series we looked at

    partial analysis, where makets wereconsidered in isolation.

    Where the income effect and repercussions

    4

    in other markets are important, partialanalysis can yield false results.

    The following example from Mas-Colell et al.

    (1995, pp. 538540) makes this evident:

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    5/165

    IntroductionWho bears the tax burden?

    1 country, Nidentical towns, Nidentical firms

    5

    ,to 1

    One firm per town

    Production function, with z= labor input:

    ( ) ( ) ( )mit ' 0 und '' 0 f z f z f z>

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    6/165

    Introduction

    Total supply of labor is M; and supply is

    inelastic.

    6

    wn is the wage in town n

    Complete factor mobility implies that

    1 ..... nw w w= = =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    7/165

    Introduction Each firm employs M/Nunits of labor.

    The following wage is the product of the optimization

    condition for firms:

    7

    Town 1 decides to tax its firm.

    ( )Marginal Cost

    Marginal Revenue

    ' MNw f=

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    8/165

    Introduction

    Owing to tax t, the optimization condition for

    firm 1 in town 1 is new.

    ( )

    ' MN

    w t f+ =

    8

    Who will actually pay the tax? The worker or

    the firm?

    Marginal Revenue

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    9/165

    Introduction

    Partial analysis

    Partial analysis investigates this questionunder the assumption that wages remain

    9

    . .,

    Because of complete factor mobility, thewage in town 1 cannot fall, thus

    2 ..... nw w w= = =

    1w w=

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    10/165

    Introduction

    Therefore, the whole tax must be carried by

    firm 1.

    10

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    11/165

    IntroductionGeneral analysis

    We now look at the general equilibrium across the

    labor markets of all the towns. As a result ofcompetition, the equilibrium wage rate must be such

    11

    as

    where the wage w(t) depends on taxation in town 1.

    The firms in towns 2, ... ,Nrespectively employ z(t)and firm 1, z1(t) units of labor.

    ( )1 2 ..... nw w w w t = = = =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    12/165

    Introduction

    The following equilibrium conditions hold:

    ( ) ( ) ( ) 11N z t z t M + =

    12

    Labor supplyLabor demand

    ( )( ) ( )

    ( )( ) ( )1

    '

    '

    f z t w t

    f z t w t t

    =

    = +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    13/165

    Introduction

    How does the wage w(t) react when the tax t

    changes?

    13

    respect to t, we obtain:

    ( ) ( ) ( )

    ( )( ) ( ) ( )

    ( )( ) ( ) ( )

    1

    1 1

    1 ' ' 0 (1)

    '' ' ' 0 (2)

    '' ' ' 1 0 (3)

    N z t z t

    f z t z t w t

    f z t z t w t

    + =

    =

    =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    14/165

    Introduction

    We can now substitute from(2) for z'(t) and

    from (3) for z1'(t) in (1).

    ( )( ) ( )' ' 1

    1 0 (4)'' ''

    w t w t N

    + + =

    14

    If we now evaluate (4) at t= 0, we obtain

    since z(0) = z1(0) = M/N.

    1

    ( ) ( ) ( )1 ' 0 ' 0 1 0 (5) N w w + + =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    15/165

    Introduction

    Solving equation (5) for w'(0) gives

    ( ) 1' 0w =

    15

    The equilibrium wage thus falls in all Ntowns.

    The reduction is smaller, the more townsthere are.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    16/165

    Introduction

    Now we still do not know who will pay the tax.

    We only know that the workers carry a portionof the tax burden.

    16

    Let a firms profit function be .

    Then aggregate profit is:

    ( )w

    ( ) ( )( ) ( )( )1N w t w t t + +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    17/165

    Introduction The change in the aggregate profit is

    If we evaluate this change when t= 0, we

    ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )( )1 ' ' ' ' 1N w t w t w t t w t + + +

    17

    Aggregate profits do not change!

    Only the workers pay!

    ( )( )1 1

    ' 0 1 0N

    wN N

    + + =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    18/165

    Introduction Although the partial equilibrium approximation

    is correct, as far as getting prices and wagesabout right, it errs by just enough and in justsuch a direction that the conclusion of the tax

    18

    incidence analysis based on it is completelyreversed.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    19/165

    Introduction This example has shown that it is often

    important to undertake a total analysis of themarkets.

    19

    That is, we have to investigate all markets andtheir mutual dependencies simultaneously.

    This is the aim and purpose of generalequilibrium theory (Walrasian Theory).

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    20/165

    IntroductionUse of the theory

    General equilibrium analysis offers a framework for

    investigating the effects of exogenous changes such

    20

    , , ,

    or politics on quantities and prices in all markets.

    It is particularly important that general equilibrium

    effects are also taken into consideration whenevaluating fiscal or structural policy measures.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    21/165

    IntroductionExamples

    Effects of an eco-tax

    21

    ec s o a or mar e po c es

    Effects of a oil price shock

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    22/165

    IntroductionAreas of application

    Public Finance

    22

    Macroeconomics

    Finance

    Trade theory

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    23/165

    Introduction Historical description of general equilibrium

    theory in a nutshell

    23

    that the wealth of the nation was based onthe division of labor and the achievement of

    economic subjects individual interests .

    The price mechanism directed by an invisible

    hand brought about intelligent coordination.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    24/165

    Introduction Adam Smiths book, An Inquiry into the

    Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations(1776), founded economic liberalism.

    24

    s centra t es s was t at se - nterestcreated (state) welfare: It is not from thebenevolence of the butcher, the brewer or thebaker that we expect our dinner, ... We

    address ourselves not to their humanity but totheir self-love, and never talk to them of ourown necessities but of their advantages.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    25/165

    Introduction L. Walras (1886) was the first to formulate a

    mathematic model taking up Adam Smithsideas of the invisible hand.

    25

    According to Walras an equilibrium is a pricevector pthat brings supply and demand in allmarkets into balance.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    26/165

    Introduction Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu applied

    Kakutanis fixed-point theorem in the 1950sin order to prove the existence of a Walrasianequilibrium subject to certain assumptions.

    26

    Already before they were able to substantiate

    the existence of Walrasian equilibria, they

    proofed the first and second fundamentaltheorems of welfare theory.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    27/165

    The Model

    These two fundamental theorems of welfaretheory constitute the theoretical foundation of

    the social market economy.

    27

    We shall give a short introduction to the

    general equilibrium model according to

    Debreu (Theory of Value, 1959).

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    28/165

    The ModelImportant assumptions of the model as presented here

    The number of goods is given.

    -

    28

    .

    Household preferences are given.

    The allocation of property rights is given (i.e., they areuniquely defined, implicitly assuming there is an efficientlegal system).

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    29/165

    The Model

    The agents exchange goods at prices thatthey regard as given.

    29

    Exchange is central and there are notransaction or information costs (frictionless

    economy).

    Prices are constituted such that all markets

    are cleared.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    30/165

    The ModelGoods

    There arej= 1,, Ngoods.

    30

    Goods are perfectly divisible.

    There is a market for every good (completemarkets).

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    31/165

    The ModelPrices

    Let pjbe the price of goodj.

    31

    We then call a pricevector.

    ( )1,....,N

    N p p p

    +=

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    32/165

    The ModelProducers (firms)

    There are f= 1,, F producers.

    32

    determined by the technology .

    The following sign convention applies for theproduction plans :

    Inputs are negative, outputs are positive.

    NfY

    ( )1,...,

    f f fN f

    y y y Y =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    33/165

    The Model

    We assume that producer fmaximizes his

    profit , given his technologicalpossibilities.

    ( )f p

    33

    That is, he solves the following problem.

    ( ) fiN

    i

    i

    Yy

    f

    Yy

    f

    Yy

    ypyppffffff

    =

    ==

    1

    maxmaxmax

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    34/165

    The ModelConsumers (Households)

    There are h= 1,,H households.

    34

    Household hstarts with the initial endowment:

    The sum of initial allocations

    is the total allocation for the economy.

    ( )1,...,N

    h h hN e e e

    +=

    1

    H

    h

    h

    e e=

    =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    35/165

    The Model The set is the set of all feasible

    consumption bundles of consumer h.

    N

    hX

    35

    Each household possesses a utility function.

    ( )1,...,h h hN h x x x X =

    :h hu X

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    36/165

    The Model Firms belong to the consumers and the profits from

    production are split among the consumers.

    Let hf be the portion of the h-th consumers share ofprofit from the f-th firm.

    36

    It holds that:

    Let the vector of the profit shares of the h-thconsumer be

    [ ]1

    0,1 und 1H

    hf hf

    h

    =

    =

    ( )1,...,h h hF =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    37/165

    The Model

    Each individual households budget is

    composed of the value of their initialendowment as well as their shares from

    com anies rofits:

    37

    ( )1

    F

    h h hf f

    f

    p x p e p=

    = +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    38/165

    The Model

    Households maximize their utility subject to their

    budget constraint.

    The decision roblem is thus:

    38

    ( ) ( )1

    max s.t.h h

    F

    h h h h hf f x X

    f

    U x p x p e p

    =

    = +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    39/165

    The ModelDefinition (Allocation): A list

    of consumption plans and production plans is

    ( ) ( )1 1, ,.., ; ,..,H Fx y x x y y=

    39

    called an allocation if

    ( )

    ( )

    1

    1

    ,.., for all 1,..,

    ,.., for all 1,..,

    h h hN h

    f f fN f

    x x x X h H

    y y y Y f F

    = =

    = =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    40/165

    The Model

    Definition: An allocation is feasible, if thefollowing holds:

    40

    ===

    +F

    f

    f

    H

    h

    h

    H

    h

    h yex111

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    41/165

    The Model

    Feasibility simply means that for eachgood the quantity consumed cannot be

    41

    .

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    42/165

    The ModelDefinition (Walrasian equilibrium). An

    allocation (x*; y*) with price vector p* is aWalrasian equilibrium if the following holds:* *1. arg max 1,..., y p y f F =

    42

    ( )

    ( )

    *

    * * * *

    1

    * * *

    1 1 1

    2. arg max s.t.

    1,...,

    3.

    f f

    h h

    y Y

    h h hx X

    F

    h h hf f f

    H H F

    h h f

    h h f

    x u x

    p x p e p y h H

    x e y

    =

    = = =

    + =

    = +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    43/165

    The ModelIn words

    In a Walrasian equilibrium all decision makerstake the price vector as given.

    43

    Firms maximize their profits and householdstheir utility.

    The price vector is such that for each goodsupply = demand.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    44/165

    The ModelQuestions

    Normative: What welfare characteristics does aWalrasian e uilibrium have was Adam Smith

    44

    right?)

    Positive: Existence and characteristics

    Empirical: Which real markets fit this model?

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    45/165

    The ModelQuestions

    Normative: Welfare properties

    45

    Positive: Existence and comparative statics

    Empirical: does the model fit the data

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    46/165

    Overview

    Behavioralhyothesis

    Exogenousdata

    Endogenousdata

    46

    Households Utilitymaximization

    EndowmentPreferences

    Prices

    FirmsProfitmaximization

    Technology Prices

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    47/165

    The ModelExample: Barter economy

    We will now calculate the Walrasianequilibrium for a barter economy in which

    47

    1 2

    households.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    48/165

    The ModelExample: Barter economy

    Initial endowment

    1 0 and 0 1e e e e e e= = = =

    48

    Utility functions

    ( ) ( )( )

    1 1

    1 11 12 11 12 2 21 22 21 22, and , ,, 0,1

    u x x x x u x x x x

    = =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    49/165

    The ModelExample: Edgeworth-Box with endowment e

    x12x21

    2ee21 = e1- ee11

    49

    x111 x22ee11

    ee22 = e2- ee12ee12

    ~2

    ~1

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    50/165

    The ModelCalculation of individual demand functions

    Household 1 solves the following problem:

    50

    11 12 1 11 12 11 12,

    1 11 2 12 1

    1 1 11 2 12

    ,

    s.t.

    where

    x x

    ax u x x x x

    p x p x b

    b p e p e

    =

    + =

    = +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    51/165

    The Model Lagrange:

    ( )111 12 1 1 11 2 12L x x b p x p x = +

    51

    ( )

    1 1

    11 12 1

    11

    11 12 2

    12

    1 1 11 2 12

    0

    1 0

    0

    L x x p

    x

    L x x px

    Lb p x p x

    = =

    = =

    = =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    52/165

    The Model Marginal rate of substitution is equal to the

    relative price12 1

    11

    x pMRS

    x

    = =

    52

    The same optimization principle applies to the

    other household.

    22 12

    21 21

    x pMRS

    x p= =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    53/165

    The Model We obtain individual demands via the budget

    constraint:

    ( )[ ]1 11 2 12

    11 1 2

    1

    ,p e p e

    x p pp

    +=

    53

    For the other household we obtain:

    ( )

    1 11 2 12

    12 1 22

    ,p e p e

    x p pp

    +=

    ( )[ ]

    ( )( )[ ]

    1 21 2 22

    21 1 2

    1

    1 21 2 22

    22 1 2

    2

    ,

    1,

    p e p e x p p p

    p e p e x p p

    p

    +

    =

    +=

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    54/165

    The ModelCalculation of equilibrium prices

    Aggregate demand = aggregate supply

    ( ) ( )11 1 2 21 1 2 11 21, ,x p p x p p e e+ = +

    54

    Aggregate demand is homogeneous of degree zero. We cantherefore normalize a price.I choose p1 = 1:

    1 11 2 12 1 21 2 22

    11 21

    1

    2

    1

    1

    e ep

    p

    p

    = +

    + =

    2 1p + =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    55/165

    The Model Equilibrium prices are thus:

    1 211,p p = =

    55

    Equilibrium consumption is thus:

    ( ) ( )

    ( ) ( )

    11 1 2 12 1 2

    21 1 2 22 1 2

    , ; ,

    , 1 ; , 1

    x p p x p p

    x p p x p p

    = =

    = =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    56/165

    56

    NORMATIVE ANALYSIS

    N i A l i

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    57/165

    Normative Analysis

    Normative analysis is concerned with the

    question of how allocations should beevaluated.

    57

    Here, we investigate the welfare properties ofWalrasian equilibria.

    Welfare evaluations are always based on

    subjective judgments.

    N i A l i

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    58/165

    Normative Analysis

    A central question of economics is: How

    should goods be allocated amonghouseholds?

    58

    We now consider 3 alternatives Welfare functions

    Voting

    Pareto Criterion

    N ti A l i

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    59/165

    Normative Analysis

    Alternative 1: Welfare functions We define a welfare function:

    59

    = u1,,uH

    and look for the allocation that maximizes

    welfare.

    N ti A l i

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    60/165

    Normative Analysis

    Examples of welfare functions W(u1, u2)

    1. The utilitarian welfare function:

    W(u1, u2) = u1 + u2

    60

    Characteristics:

    (a) Symmetry: W(u1, u2) = W(u2, u1)

    Symmetry has the advantage that welfare does notdepend on the name of the consumer, but rather oneveryone being considered in the same way.

    N ti A l i

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    61/165

    Normative Analysis

    (b) Always give the most to the individual with the greatestmarginal utility. This function awards something to the

    individual who can produce greater utility with thegoods.

    61

    .

    W(u1, u2) = min{u1, u2}

    Characteristics:

    (a) Symmetry: W(u1, u2) = W(u2, u1)

    (b) Give to the one with the least utility.

    Normati e Anal sis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    62/165

    Normative Analysis

    Criticism of welfare functions

    Who chooses W(u1,, uH)?

    62

    An interpersonal comparison of utility is required.

    Individuals have an incentive to hide their truepreferences if they see an advantage in doing so.

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    63/165

    Normative Analysis

    Interpersonal comparison of utility requires a

    cardinal utility concept. The possibility of this,however, is questionable and is the reason why anordinal utility concept has become accepted.

    63

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    64/165

    Normative Analysis

    Alternative 2: Voting

    Derivation of a welfare function based on individualhousehold preferences decided by means of majorityvoting choices.

    64

    Condorcet Paradox

    Arrows Impossibility Theorem

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    65/165

    Normative Analysis

    Condorcet Paradox

    Condorcets paradox illustrates that the familiarmethod of majority voting can fail to satisfy thetransitivit re uirement.

    65

    Let there be 3 social states a, b, c:

    Player 1 a b c

    Player 2 b c a

    Player 3 c a b

    ( ) ( ) ( )cubuau 111 >>

    ( ) ( ) ( )aucubu 222 >>

    ( ) ( ) ( )buaucu 333 >>

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    66/165

    Normative Analysis

    Voting:

    a vs. b: Players 1 and 3 find a better.Thus W(a) > W(b)

    66

    Thus W(b) > W(c)a vs. c: Players 2 and 3 find c better.

    Thus W(c) > W(a)

    Thus W(a) > W(b) > W(c) > W(a) which is acontradiction.

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    67/165

    Normative Analysis

    Arrows Impossibility Theorem

    Arrows impossibility theorem shows the impossibilityof aggregating individual preferences (finding a votingrule) so as to establish a social preference order that

    67

    is free of contradictions.

    It states that:If there are at least three social states, then there is

    no social welfare function that satisfies the preciselyspecified minimal requirements for a reasonablesocial welfare function.

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    68/165

    Normative Analysis

    Minimal requirements for areasonable social welfare function

    Unrestricted Domain: The social preference orderthat is derived from individual preferences must becom lete reflexive and transitive.

    68

    Independence of irrelevant alternatives: Theassessment of two alternatives should beindependent of that of other alternatives.

    Weak Pareto Principle

    Nondictatorship: The preference of any one

    individual may not be declared the social preference.

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    69/165

    Normative Analysis

    Kenneth Arrow (1963) has shown that no socialdecision mechanism exists that can satisfy theseconditions.

    69

    The result is sobering; it shows that no guarantee for

    rational decisions exists in politics.

    It also explains why collective decisions can be

    arbitrary.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    70/165

    Pareto Efficiency

    Alternative 3: Pareto Criterion

    Definition: Given an allocation x. A feasible allocation y -

    70

    .

    Definition: Given an allocation x. An feasible allocationyis weakly Pareto-better if all agents do not find yless preferable to x, and at least one agent prefers y.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    71/165

    Pareto Efficiency

    Definition (Pareto-efficiency): an allocation xisPareto-efficient if it does not allow any weak

    Pareto-improvement.

    71

    An allocation is Pareto-efficient if it isimpossible to make someone better off

    without making someone worse off.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    72/165

    Pareto Efficiency

    Remarks:

    This criterion gives every economic subject a vetoright.

    72

    Efficiency has nothing to do with justice (whatever itsdefinition): An allocation in which an agent consumesall goods is Pareto-efficient.

    In general there are many Pareto-efficient allocations.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    73/165

    Pareto Efficiency

    Example: Barter economy

    2 agents, 2 goods x1 and x2

    Initial allocation 1 and 1e e= =

    73

    Utility functions

    ( ) ( )( )

    1 1

    1 11 12 11 12 2 21 22 21 22, und , ,, 0,1

    u x x x x u x x x x

    = =

    and

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    74/165

    Pareto Efficiency

    Calculation of Pareto-efficient allocations:

    ( ) 11 11 12 11 12,ax u x x x x

    =

    74

    ( )

    , , ,

    12 21 22 21 22 2

    11 21

    12 22

    s.t. ,

    1

    1

    u x x x x u

    x x

    x x

    = =

    + =

    + =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    75/165

    a y

    Lagrange:

    ( ) ( )( )11

    11 12 2 11 121 1 L x x u x x

    =

    75

    ( ) ( )

    ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

    ( ) ( )

    1 11 1

    11 12 11 12

    11

    11 12 11 1212

    1

    2 11 12

    1 1 0

    1 1 1 1 0

    1 1 0

    L x x x x

    x

    L

    x x x xx

    Lu x x

    = =

    = =

    = =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    76/165

    y

    Marginal rates of substitution:

    ( ) ( )12 12

    1 2

    11 11

    11 1 1

    x x RS MRSx x

    = = =

    76

    Solve for x12 (contract curve):

    ( )

    ( )

    ( )11

    1211

    1

    where1 1 1

    x

    x x

    = =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    77/165

    y

    Edgeworth-Box: Contract curve

    x12

    x21 2xx

    21

    = e1

    - xx11

    x

    77

    The contract curve is the set of all Pareto-efficientallocations.

    x111 x22xx11

    xx22 = e2- xx12xx12

    ~2~1

    ( )12

    111 1x

    x =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    78/165

    y

    How does a contract curve look like?

    ( )12

    2

    11 11

    01 1

    dx

    dx x

    = >

    ( ) ( )

    ( )

    2

    111242

    11 11

    2 1 1 11 1

    xd xdx x

    =

    78

    ( )

    ( )

    ( )

    ( )( )

    ( )

    2

    122

    11

    2

    12

    2

    11

    2

    12

    2

    11

    1

    If 1, then 0.1

    1If 1, then 0.

    1

    1If 1, then 0.

    1

    d x

    dx

    d x

    dx

    d x

    dx

    = >

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    79/165

    y

    The example demonstrates that an allocation

    is only Pareto-efficient if the marginal rate ofsubstitution between two goods is identical

    for both households.

    79

    This statement can be extended to any

    number of goods and households: An

    allocation is only then Pareto-efficient if themarginal rate of substitution between anytwo goods is the same for all individuals.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    80/165

    y

    Edgeworth-Box: Inefficient allocation

    x12x21 2xx21 = e1- xx11

    80

    x111 x22xx11

    xx22 = e2- xx12xx12

    ~2

    ~1

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    81/165

    Edgeworth-Box: Efficient allocation

    x212xx21 = e1- xx11

    81

    x111 x22xx11

    xx22 = e2- xx12xx12

    ~2

    ~1

    Slopes of the indifference curves are

    identical.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    82/165

    Example: Production economy

    Consider the following allocation problem: Player 1produces qB bananas and player 2, qO oranges.

    82

    Let the cost functions be c(qi) = qi, i= B,O.

    Let the utility functions of both players for bananas

    and oranges be u1(qO) and u2(qB) where

    ' ''0 und 0, 1, 2.i i

    u u i> < =and

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    83/165

    Payoff to both players:

    u1(qO) qB for player 1u2(qB) qO for player 2

    83

    Calculate the Pareto-efficient allocations:

    ( ) ( )

    ( )

    1 2 1,

    2 2

    max

    s.t.O B

    O Bq q

    B O

    S S u q q

    u q q S

    =

    =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    84/165

    Lagrange function:

    ( )1 2 2L SB Bu u q q=

    84

    Pareto-efficient production and consumptiongiven S2

    [ ] ( )1 2' ' 1 0O Bu q u q =

    ( ) ( )* *2 2,B Oq S q S

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    85/165

    Curve of the Pareto-efficient allocations

    ( ){ ( )* *

    1 1 2 2 2 2S S S SB Bu u q q

    =

    85

    envelope theorem):

    The curve is concave:

    11

    2

    S' 0

    Su

    =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    86/165

    The curve of Pareto-efficient allocations:

    S1Pareto-efficient

    86

    S2

    Pareto-

    inefficient

    allocations

    S1(S2)

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    87/165

    In order to get an initial idea of the relationship

    between Walrasian equilibrium and Pareto-efficiency,

    let us once again look at the first-order conditions of abarter economy with two households (h= 1,2) andtwo oods i= 1 2 .

    87

    ( )

    ( )

    11 12 21 22

    1 11 12, , ,

    2 2

    2 21, 22 2

    1 1

    max ,

    s.t. and

    x x x x

    h h

    h h

    u x x

    x e u x x u= =

    =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    88/165

    Lagrange:

    First order conditions:

    ( ) ( )( )

    2 2 2

    1 11 12 2 2 21 22 21 1 1, ,i hi hii h hL u x x e x u x x u = = =

    = + +

    88

    iMultipliers

    ( )

    ( )

    1 11 12

    1 1

    2 21 22

    2

    2 2

    , 0, 1,2

    ,0, 1,2

    i

    i i

    i

    i i

    u x xL ix x

    u x xLi

    x x

    = = =

    = = =

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    89/165

    Identical marginal rates of substitution:

    ( ) ( )1 11 12 2 21 2211 1 21 1

    1 2

    , ,

    ,, ,

    u x x u x xx x

    MRS MRSu x x u x x

    = = = =

    89

    The multipliers can be interpreted as the

    prices p1 and p2.

    12 22x x

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    90/165

    The optimality conditions of the previous the

    maximization problems are identical with the

    optimality conditions of a Walrasianequilibrium!

    90

    In a Walrasian equilibrium, the followingholds:

    1 1

    1 22 2

    und

    p p

    MRS MRSp p= =and

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    91/165

    The multipliers ireflect the fact that the endowment

    of goods is scarce.

    If we differentiate the Lagrange function with respectto the endowment ei we get i.

    91

    , i

    could get if we had a bit more of good i. Since we have just seen that the multipliers and

    prices enter in the same way into the first-order

    conditions of the two problems, it is clear that prices

    also reflect scarcity of goods.

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    92/165

    Edgeworth-Box: Walrasian equilibrium

    x12x212xx21 = e1- xx11

    92

    x111 x22xx11

    xx22 = e2- xx12xx12

    ~2

    ~1

    x*

    e*

    Pareto Efficiency

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    93/165

    We have just seen that there is a close

    relationship between Pareto efficiency andWalrasian equilibrium.

    93

    This relationship is investigated in thefollowing welfare theorems.

    Normative Analysis

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    94/165

    94

    The Welfare Theorems

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    95/165

    Theorem (First Welfare Theorem).

    Consider a general equilibrium model with

    local non-satiated references. Furthermore

    95

    let (p*, x*, y*) be a Walrasian equilibrium.Then the allocation (x*, y*) is Pareto-efficient.

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    96/165

    Proof (indirect):

    Let (p*, x*, y*) be a Walrasian equilibrium and(x, y) an allocation that is Pareto-better.

    96

    -

    that*

    1 1

    *

    for household 1

    2,...,h h

    x x

    x x h H =

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    97/165

    Why has household 1 not chosen x1 withprices p*?

    Goods bundle x1 must be more expensive

    97

    than x1* with prices p*, otherwise household

    1 would not have maximized its utility:

    1 1* * *p x p x >

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    98/165

    For all other households,

    must hold owing to local nonsatiation.

    * * *h h

    p x p x

    98

    Summing across all households yields:* * *

    1 1

    H H

    h h

    h h

    p x p x= =

    >

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    99/165

    Owing to local non-satiation, a utility-

    maximizing consumption bundle must

    exhaust the budget; i.e.,

    H H H F

    99

    ( )

    ( ) ( )

    * * * * *

    1 1 1 1

    * * *

    1 1 1

    1

    * * * * *

    1 1 1 1

    h h hf f

    h h h f

    H F H

    h hf f

    h f h

    H F H F

    h f h f

    h f h f

    p x p e p y

    p e p y

    p e p y p e p y

    = = = =

    = = =

    =

    = = = =

    = +

    = +

    = + +

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    100/165

    The last inequality is an implication of thefirms profit maximization.

    But this then gives

    ( )+>H F

    h

    H

    h

    H

    h ypepxpxp*****

    100

    A contradiction of the assumption that theproposed allocation is feasible; that is

    1 1 1

    H H F

    h h f

    h h f

    x e y= = =

    +

    +>

    = ===

    = ===

    H

    h

    F

    f

    fh

    H

    h

    h

    H

    h

    h

    h fhh

    yepxpxp1 1

    *

    1

    **

    1

    *

    1 111

    !

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    101/165

    "To say it in words"

    An allocation B, which is Pareto-better

    than competition allocation A, mustcost more than A, since, otherwise, the

    latter would not represent the

    101

    competition equilibrium. In order to

    afford B, household incomes would haveto rise. However, with the given

    allocation this would only be possible

    if profits were to rise. Since firms

    behave in a profit-maximizing manner,Bs profit is lower than that of A.

    Thus, B is not viable.

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    102/165

    The first welfare theorem shows that the marketmechanism achieves an efficient allocation.

    The market mechanism is a very simple mechanism:

    102

    Economic agents only have to know prices and their

    own preferences and production technology.

    However, the question of who sets prices when all

    economic agents are price takers remainsunanswered.

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    103/165

    Conditions for the first theorem to hold:

    No external effectsThe utility of a consumer depends only on the

    103

    goo s un e t at e, mse , consumes.

    Opposite example: cigarette consumption

    Local nonsatiation.

    Convexity is no condition.

    First Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    104/165

    Definition (local nonsatiation): The property of local nonsatiation ofconsumer preferences states that for any bundle of goods there isalways another bundle of goods arbitrarily close that is preferred to it.

    Notes (Definition and comments are from wikipedia):

    1. Local nonsatiation is implied by monotonicity of preferences, but not viceversa. ence s a wea er con on.

    2. There is no requirement that the preferred bundle y contain more of anygood - hence, some goods can be "bads" and preferences can be non-monotone.

    3. It rules out the extreme case where all goods are "bads", since then the

    point x = 0 would be a bliss point.

    4. The consumption set must be either unbounded or open (in other words,it cannot be compact). If it were compact it would necessarily have abliss point, which local nonsatiation rules out.

    Local Nonsatiation

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    105/165

    To illustrate that local nonsatiation is a

    necessary condition for the first welfare

    theorem, we consider an economy with twohouseholds and two goods in which this

    105

    characteristic is absent.

    Local Nonsatiation

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    106/165

    Edgeworth-Box: Local nonsatiation

    x12x21 2

    106

    x111 x22~2

    x*

    e

    ~2

    ~1

    c n erence

    curvex

    Local Nonsatiation

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    107/165

    The allocation x* is a Walrasian equilibrium,but it is not Pareto-efficient!

    107

    Player 1 has local non-satiated preferences;i.e., he has thick indifference curves.

    He is therefore indifferent to xand x*, but xisstrictly preferable for consumer 2!

    Second Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    108/165

    Theorem (Second Welfare Theorem):

    Under certain conditions every Pareto-

    108

    Walrasian equilibrium by means of a suitableselection of property rights.

    Second Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    109/165

    Idea of the second welfare theorem

    The Pareto-efficient allocation xshould be realized.Initial endowmentis e.

    109

    x

    1

    e

    Second Welfare Theorem

    S 1 L k f i h h h b d i h

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    110/165

    Step 1: Look for price vector p, such that the budget constraint thatpasses through e, has the same slope as the tangent to the twoindifferent curves at point x.

    2

    110

    1

    e

    x

    Second Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    111/165

    Step 2: Redistribution (by means of taxes and transfers) of theinitial allocation eto e'.

    2

    111

    1

    e'

    x e

    Second Welfare Theorem

    W di th lifi t i

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    112/165

    We now discuss the qualifier certain

    conditions in the statement of the theorem.

    112

    Convexity

    Local nonsatiation

    Second Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    113/165

    Convexity (Households)

    113

    .

    Remarks: If a preference ordering is convex,then the upper contour set is convex.

    Second Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    114/165

    x2

    {y: y x} Upper contour set ofx

    114

    x1

    1

    ~1

    x

    Remark:{y: y x} is called the upper contour set of x.

    {y: y> x} is called the strict upper contour set of x.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    115/165

    Second Welfare Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    116/165

    Allocation x is Pareto-efficient, however notfeasible as a Walrasian equilibrium.

    116

    consumption bundle x2 = (x21, x22) on thebudget constraint line, consumer 1 wouldprefer the allocation y1 = (y11, y12).

    Second Welfare Theorem

    Convexity (Firms)

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    117/165

    Convexity (Firms)

    Every production set Yf is convex:

    117

    No increasing economies of scale

    No indivisibility No fixed costs

    Second Welfare Theorem

    Examples of non convex technologies:

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    118/165

    Examples of non-convex technologies:

    Fixed costs IndivisibilityIncreasing

    118

    scale

    0 00

    Second Welfare Theorem

    Example of fixed costs

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    119/165

    a p s s

    An economy is assumed to consist of a consumer, h= 1,and two goods n= 2, the work of the consumer and theconsumption goods produced by his labor. ("Robinson

    "

    119

    - .

    The production function is characterized by fixed costs.

    Pareto-efficiency requires that the marginal rate of

    substitution is equal to the technical rate of substitution(MRS = TRS).

    Second Welfare Theorem

    Decentralization is possible

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    120/165

    Decentralization is possible

    y2

    ~1

    120y1 0

    p

    x

    Yf

    Second Welfare Theorem

    Decentralization is not possible

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    121/165

    Decentralization is not possible

    y2~1

    121

    y1

    p

    x

    Yf

    Second Welfare Theorem

    Allocation x is Pareto-efficient but not

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    122/165

    Allocation xis Pareto efficient, but notachievable as a Walrasian equilibrium, since

    it does not maximize the producers profit!

    122

    Problem: Technology Yf is not convex. Thefirm makes losses.

    Interpretation of the Welfare Theorems

    Until now we have discussed the welfare theorems from

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    123/165

    a theoretical point of view. On the next few slides

    well point out some difficulties arising from adaptingthese findings to the real-world.

    123

    Our focus will be on the following issues:

    1. Market Economy vs. Planned Economy

    2. Redistribution of the initial allocation

    3. Market Failure as a real-word problem

    Market Economy vs. Planned Economy

    From Wikipedia:

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    124/165

    p

    The first theorem is often taken to be an analyticalconfirmation of Adam Smith's "invisible hand"

    124

    ,toward the efficient allocation of resources.

    The theorem supports a case for non-intervention inideal conditions: let the markets do the work and theoutcome will be Pareto efficient.

    Market Economy vs. Planned Economy

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    125/165

    Statement: The economic policy maker only has todetermine property rights in a market economy and canleave efficient allocation to the market. The marketeconomy is thus better than a planned economy.

    125

    This is a fallacious statement, as in a centrally plannedeconomy with perfect information exactly the samesolution can be achieved. Both systems are equivalent

    in this respect.

    Market Economy vs. Planned Economy

    What can be said if the assumption of complete

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    126/165

    informationby the planner is dropped?

    - With a planned economy the likelihood of arriving at a

    126

    .thus almost always inefficient.

    - With a market economy an efficient allocation isguaranteed (first welfare theorem). But it is very

    improbable that the realized allocation coincides withthe targeted allocation.

    Redistribution of the initial allocation

    2. Redistribution of the initial allocation

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    127/165

    To reach the target allocation, the policy maker has

    two fundamental ways to influence the initialallocation:

    - -

    127

    Since reallocation occurs independently of thedemand behavior of economic subjects on the

    markets, the marginal conditions remain intact.Thus, this type of reallocation is efficient.

    Redistribution of the initial allocation

    b) Commodity-/consumption-/income taxes

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    128/165

    These reallocations are dependent on the

    transactions and the behavior of market subjects. Adifference arises between the purchase and sales

    128

    .

    The second welfare theorem only holds for areallocation of type a. In the real world, however, a

    reallocation of type b is almost always the caseobserved.

    Market Failure as a real-word problem

    3. Market Failure as a real-word problem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    129/165

    The fundamental theorems indicate why markets might fail toprovide efficient allocations.

    Reasons for market failures:

    129

    proper y r g s are no we e ne

    incomplete markets

    incomplete information

    transaction costs

    Non-convexities

    Markets may also fail if the utility- and production functions ofthe agents are dependent on the consumption or production ofthe other economic subjects (external effects).

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    130/165

    130

    Positive Analysis

    Literature: Varian, H., Microeconomic AnalysisC

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    131/165

    (Chapter 17)

    In this section we shall look at

    131

    Walrass Law,

    Relative and absolute prices

    Existence of Walrasian equilibrium.

    Walrass Law

    We consider a barter economy.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    132/165

    A consumers demand is defined as

    132

    ( )

    ( )

    ( )

    1 ,

    ,

    ,

    h h

    h h

    hN h

    x p e

    x p e

    x p e

    =

    Walrass Law

    The consumers excess demand (net

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    133/165

    demand) is

    ( ) ( ),h h h hz p x p e e=

    133

    Aggregate excess demand is then

    ( ) ( ) ( )( )1 1 ,

    H H

    h h h h

    h hz p z p x p e e

    = == =

    Walrass Law

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    134/165

    Theorem (Walrass law). For everyprice vector p, thevalue of aggregate excess demand is equal to zero;

    i.e.,

    134

    ( ) 0 p z p =

    Walrass Law

    Proof

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    135/165

    Owing to monotonicity, every households demandsatisfies the budget constraint

    135

    Thus it follows that

    Aggregate

    ( ) ( )1

    0H

    h

    h

    p z p p z p=

    = =

    ,h h h

    ( ) ( )( ), 0h h h hp z p p x p e e = =

    Walrass Law

    Remarks:

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    136/165

    The value of excess demand is always zero.

    136

    The law implies that if N-1 markets are inequilibrium, the Nthmarket will also be inequilibrium.

    Relative Prices

    Demand is homogeneous of degree zero for

    prices:

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    137/165

    prices:

    *HomogenittsgradDegree of homogeneity

    137

    Interpretation: If one multiplies all prices by

    the factor , demand does not change (nomoney illusion!).

    ( )

    ( ) ( )

    *

    0

    , , ,h h h h h hx p e x p e x p e = =

    Relative Prices

    Cobb-Douglas example:

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    138/165

    For a barter economy with two goods we getthe following demand:

    138

    The budget constraint is

    Demand for good 1 is homogeneous:

    ( ) ( )11 21 2

    , and ,h h h h

    x p e x p ep p

    = =

    1 1 1 2 2h hb p e p e= +

    ( )( ) ( )

    ( )1 1 2 2 1 1 2 21 11 1

    , ,h h h h

    h h h h

    p e p e p e p e x p e x p e

    p p

    + += = =

    Relative Prices

    An important implication is that only relative

    prices are relevant to demand

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    139/165

    prices are relevant to demand.

    139

    freely.

    The price of the first good is often given as

    numraire...

    Relative Prices

    The prices then have to be changed using theformula

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    140/165

    1, 1,..,

    ii

    p p i N p= =

    140

    The price of good 1 is thus normalized to .

    Every price is thus measured in the units of the firstgood.

    1 1p =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    141/165

    141

    Walrasian Equilibrium

    Existence

    It is often important to know whether the

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    142/165

    It is often important to know whether the

    objects that are being discussed actuallyexist.

    142

    If one assumes that certain things exist even

    though they do not in fact exist, this can result

    in funny conclusions.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    143/165

    "Raelians" believe thatextraterrestials broughtlife to the each 25,000

    143

    years ago.

    Existence

    27.10.07 7:56 Kantonal police of the Valais

    In the Valais paintball guns are used to shoot at

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    144/165

    In the Valais paintball guns are used to shoot at

    Raelians.

    144

    . .being held by the Raelian sect on Friday evening in

    the lower Valais village of Mige and shot aroundwith a paintball gun. Two people were slightly injured.

    According to the Valais police report, approximately

    40 members of the UFO-sect were conducting ameeting in a large hall in Mige when the unknownperson intruded on the crowd and fired. The culpritthen took flight.

    Existence

    Proposition (Humbug): The largest integer number is 1.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    145/165

    Proof: Let us suppose that a finitely large integernumber exists and let it be called N. Then,

    2

    145

    since Nis the largest number. Thus

    But since Nis the largest number,

    QED.

    1N

    1N=

    Existence

    We have only arrived at this nonsense

    because we have assumed the existence of a

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    146/165

    because we have assumed the existence of a

    largest integer number.

    146

    But there is no such number and therefore

    the proof is humbug.

    Existence

    In order to investigate the existence of a Walrasian

    equilibrium, we will assume that every good has a

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    147/165

    positive excess demand when its price is equal tozero; i.e.,

    147

    Then a Walrasian equilibrium is a price vector p*,such that aggregate excess demand is z(p*) = 0.

    This means that supply = demand for every good.

    or a ,..,i i p z p= =

    Existence

    Proof of existence

    In order to prove its existence it must be shown that

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    148/165

    In order to prove its existence, it must be shown that

    there is a price vector p*, such that z(p*) = 0; i.e.,

    148

    We thus have an equilibrium system with Nequationsand Nunknowns.

    ( )

    1

    0

    0

    0Nz p

    =

    =

    =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    149/165

    Existence

    However, since z(p) is homogeneous of degree zeroin prices, we are free to select a price.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    150/165

    Thus the system of equations which we would like to

    150

    -

    N-1 unknown prices:

    ( )

    ( )

    1

    1

    0

    0

    0

    0N

    z p

    z p

    =

    =

    =

    =

    Existence

    A Walrasian equilibrium exists if we can find a

    solution to this system of equations.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    151/165

    151

    of a fixed-point theorem.

    The simplest fixed-point theorem is Brouwers

    fixed-point theorem.

    Existence

    Digression: Brouwers Fixed-Point Theorem

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    152/165

    Theorem. If is a continuousfunction, then an xexists with f(x) = x.

    11

    :

    NN

    SSf

    152

    Proof (for N= 2): Consider a continuous function .

    The theorem states that this function has a

    fixpoint; i.e., such that

    :[0,1] [0,1]f

    [ ]0,1x ( ) . f x x=

    Existence

    Define the function .

    The function gmeasures the distance between f(x)

    ( ) ( )g x f x x=

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    153/165

    and the diagonal:f(x)

    1530 1

    1

    x

    Existence

    A fixpoint x* of the function fthus satisfies

    g(x*) = 0. f(x)

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    154/165

    Since f(0) [0,1], it holds that1

    154

    - .

    Since f(1) [0,1], it holds that

    g(1) = f(1)-1 0.

    Since the function fis continuous, it follows at anx* [0,1] exists, such that g(x*) = 0 = f(x*) - x*.End of digression.

    0 1x

    Existence

    Proof of existence (continuation):

    We allow that excess demand z(p*) can be negative

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    155/165

    We allow that excess demand z(p ) can be negative

    in a Walrasian equilibrium (Demand < Supply).

    155

    A Walrasian equilibrium is then a price vector p*,

    such that aggregate demand z(p*) 0.

    The proof of existence involves to show that a price

    vector p*exists, such that z(p*) 0.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    156/165

    Existence

    Unity simplex of

    N

    N

    +

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    157/165

    1

    11

    N N

    i

    iS p p

    +

    =

    = =

    157

    S1S2

    2p

    2p

    1p

    1

    p

    3p

    Existence

    The proof of existence involves to show thata normalized price vector p SN-1 exists such

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    158/165

    that z(p) 0.

    158

    The proof uses Brouwers fixed-point

    theorem.

    Existence

    Theorem (Existence): If excess demand

    is continuous, then a price1: N Nz S

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    159/165

    , p

    vector p* SN-1 exists such that z(p*) 0.

    :z S

    159

    Proof:

    Consider the function 11: NN SSg

    ( )( )

    ( )( )( )

    1

    max 0,1,...,

    1 max 0,

    i ii N

    j

    j

    p z pg p i N

    z p=

    +

    = =+

    Existence

    Since z(p) and max(...) are continuousfunctions, then g(p) is also continuous.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    160/165

    Since the ran e of this function is1N

    =

    160

    the simplex SN-1.

    Interpretation of g: If there is a surplusdemand for good i; i.e., z

    i(p) > 0, then the

    price of this good will rise.

    1i=

    Existence

    The function gthus has the properties that weneed in order to apply Brouwers fixed-point

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    161/165

    theorem.

    161

    It follows from Brouwers fixed-point theorem

    that a p* exists such that p* = g(p*); and

    ( )( )

    ( )( )

    *

    *

    1

    max 0, *(*) 1

    1 max 0, *

    i i

    i N

    j

    j

    p z p p i ,...,N

    z p=

    += =

    +

    Existence

    It still needs to be proved that the fixpoint p*is a Walrasian equilibrium; i.e., z(p*) 0.

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    162/165

    *

    162

    ( )( ) ( )( )*1

    max 0, * max 0, * 1N

    i j i

    j

    p z p z p i ,...,N =

    = =

    Existence

    Multiplication of the equation with zi(p*)

    ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( ) ,...,Nipzpzpzppz iiN

    jii 1*,0max**,0max**

    ==

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    163/165

    j 1

    =

    163

    ,

    Walrass law thus implies

    ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( )*1 1 1

    0

    * max 0, * * max 0, *

    N N N

    i i j i i

    i j i

    z p p z p z p z p= = =

    =

    =

    ( ) ( )( )1

    0 * max 0, *N

    i i

    i

    z p z p=

    =

    Existence

    Each term

    ( ) ( )( )* max 0, * 1,...,i i z p z p i N =

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    164/165

    is greater than or equal to zero:

    ( ) ( )( )

    164

    ( ) ( ) ( )( )

    ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )2

    If * 0, then * max 0, * 0

    If * 0, then * max 0, * *

    i i i

    i i i i

    z p z p z p

    z p z p z p z p

    =

    > =

    Existence

    If one term were indeed greater than zero,

    ( ) ( )( )0 * max 0, *N

    i i z p z p=

  • 8/3/2019 03 Micro Walras

    165/165

    could not be satisfied.1i=

    165

    Thus it holds that zi(p*) 0 i= 1,..,N.

    Therefore p* is a Walrasian equilibrium.

    QED