efa-paper-101213

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    1/27

    1

    NORWEGIAN ECONOMY

    WHAT DOES THE NORDIC MODEL HAVE TO DO WITH IT?

    Birmingham Business SchoolDept of Political Science, 13th

    of December 2010

    Eivind Falkum, Fafo institute of applied social science, Oslo

    1 Introduction

    The Nordic region is like the bumble bee: it flies, against all rules of aerodynamics. (C.

    Ketel, Nordic Globalisation Barometer 2008)

    The Nordic countries had on average productivity rates 17 per cent higher than the rest of the

    OECD states in 2007. They were all in the top 14 of the World Bank ranking for ease of doing

    business in 2007 (Quintin Peel 2008). The economic growth and the wealth of the Nordic nations

    after World War II are often explained by the special combination of labour regulations,

    collaboration between employers and employees and quite generous welfare state offers, all

    referred to as elements of the Nordic model.

    Norway has been criticized by OECD for having too generous welfare offers and to low income

    gaps to be competitive in global markets. Many economists and politicians have turned to the

    bumble bee metaphor when the Norwegian economy is discussed after the financial crisis in

    2008. The levels of public expenditures should make the Norwegian economy fall during the last

    30 years, and not grow to the levels of today according to economic theory. All the Nordic

    countries were drabbed by the financial crisis in the autumn of 2008, but Norway came out

    almost unharmed during 2009 compared to most other countries, and despite heavy

    unemployment forecasts in the beginning of that year. OECD lately defined Norway to have

    managed the financial crisis very well compared to other nations. This is partly to be explained

    by oil incomes and the governmental funding of oil incomes at the pt amount of about 370

    billion.

    However, the Norwegian government praises the Norwegian modelas the main reason for the

    economic growth and success, including the way to handle large national oil incomes. The

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    2/27

    2

    Norwegian government then makes a distinction between the Nordic and the Norwegian models,

    claiming that there are special elements in the Norwegian model that are not present in the other

    Nordic countries. Even Norwegian investors and capitalists now embrace the Nordic model by

    initiating it to be a major theme on the Davos Economic Forum in 2011. Liberal and

    conservative political parties that have opposed most of labour and welfare reforms in Norway

    over the years are now hailing the Norwegian practice of the model. Nowadays there is a

    political rivalry: who invented and who owns the Norwegian model?

    This article will discuss the Nordic model and how it is practiced in Norway. Special attention is

    paid to the way it is related to the national political and economic systems. The article has five

    parts. First it outlines a theoretic perspective. Second is the analysis of the historic development

    of the Norwegian model. The third part is an analysis of the elements in the model that affects

    the economy. Part four presents the institutional development of the industrial relations. The fifth

    part discusses the potentials for development and economic growth in the Nordic model. The

    sixth and final part discusses the findings and analyses the Nordic model 1) as a political and

    economic hybrid and 2) as an investment scheme. Data are historical sources and analysis of the

    Norwegian labour market and welfare state (Falkum 2008), national statistics from Statistics

    Norway, case studies of enterprises (Falkum 2008, Stensaker et al 2011 (in print)) and a labour

    market survey in a random sample of employers and employees (Falkum et.al 2009).

    2 Theoretic approach

    The Nordic model has been identified and discussed by researchers since the late 1960s.

    Labour and business research referred to the Scandinavian model with strong unions, strong

    employers associations and industrial relations based on collective bargaining and basic

    agreements that regulated the labour markets (Reve 1974). During the 1960s and 1970s human

    relations oriented concepts of work place democracy were added to the model by employee

    participation programs (Trist et al 1963, Thorsrud & Emery 1970).

    Welfare research focused on social security programs, health care offers and education systems

    as empirical fields. Distribution of public offers, taxation and incomes was related to the

    organization and performance of public services (yen). In the 1980s studies focused on social

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    3/27

    3

    justice and equality between social groups and classes (Jacobsen et al 1982). Welfare research

    referred to the Scandinavian countries, Finland and Iceland as included in the Nordic model.

    Later on the Nordic model was conceptually interpreted as a specific welfare state principle of

    democratic and just distributions of national wealth (Hippe 19). More nations than the Nordic

    countries, for instance Canada, New Zealand and Netherland were perceived or interpreted as

    practicing such welfare state principles. Welfare state researchers then left the perception of a

    geographic defined model for a theoretic and conceptual welfare state model based on universal

    rights and services.

    However, the Nordic model was never a readymade scheme, a political program or a master plan

    that in detail described what to do, how to do it and by whom. The idea of a specific

    combination of labour and welfare policies evolved separately, but simultaneously over most of

    the last century in Denmark, Sweden, Norway and several other European countries. Therefore

    there are, and have always been different ways to practice the model. In the 1970s the

    Scandinavian model was the term used by researchers (for instance Reve 1974). Later on,

    probably through the development of inter Nordic political relations and establishment of Nordic

    Council, the Nordic model became a common term. However, it was still not precisely defined or

    described. The model consists more of some principles about distribution of rights, participation,

    influence and wealth that guides decisions and policies.

    Institutional perspective

    In Norway the Nordic model is the national sum of political, economic and social outcomes of

    long term development of industrial relations, and changes in politics, economy and welfare

    programs that were derived from these industrial relations as they emerged. This makes theories

    of institutionalization relevant and useful to reveal and explain how the Nordic model evolved

    and how it works in the societies. The national industrial relations become a driver of

    development. Thus it is reasonable to focus on the work life context as an arena for

    institutionalization of the model.

    March & Olsen (1995:28) defines political institutions as 1) regulation by rights and rules, 2)

    identification and preferences (norms) and 3) meaning and understanding (cognition). This

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    4/27

    4

    definition is in line with Scotts (1995) conceptualization of institutions. Institutions contribute to

    stability, security and predictability in social systems (Hernes 1975: 52-58, Mayhew 1982: 11,

    March & Olsen 1995: 31, Scott 1995: 49). This theoretic framework can help to understand how

    the Nordic model developed and how it works. Labour conditions, labour relations and

    distribution of wealth and welfare are regulated by rights, obligations and formal rules. For the

    time being the identification with the Nordic model are strong in most social groups, at least in

    Norway, and it represents the preferred ways to do things (Falkum 2008). Meanings and

    understanding of society are shared to a large extent. The Nordic countries are socially stable,

    secure and predictable societies compared with others. Scott (1995:138) describes the

    predictability of individual behaviour in institutionalised systems in this way:

    As situations become more highly institutionalized, individuals accept and follow social scripts,

    routines and performance programsbecause they are accepted as the way things are doneby

    persons like me in situations like this.

    It is the third element in March & Olsens definition that is important to discuss. How do

    opposing actors with very different opinions and interests at stake develop shared understandings

    of reality, agreed solutions to problems and consensus on procedures and decisions about the

    ways to organize and govern work life and welfare? How does such a truth regime (Foucault1982) develop and how does it work? These are the essential questions to discuss in order to

    explain if and how institutions can guide and govern political and economic systems.

    Narrowing the scopeeconomy, work and welfare

    Norwegian economy has grown constantly for decades. GNP per capita in 2007 was almost 180

    percent more than GNP per capita in 1970 (in fixed currency), and almost 2 times more than the

    average GNP per capita in EU27. Export of oil & gas contributes substantially to the growth, but

    the onshore economy is growing more than the average national growth the last five years

    (www.ssb.no).

    Employment rate is 72 percent of the workforce aged 15 74 in 2010. Women have entered

    work life during the last 30 years and the female employment rate is only slightly lower than the

    http://www.ssb.no/http://www.ssb.no/http://www.ssb.no/http://www.ssb.no/
  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    5/27

    5

    male rate. 35 percent of women at the age of 30 years have tertiary education on university level,

    compared to 30 percent of men at the same age (www.ssb.no)

    Almost 700 000 persons in the work force are excluded from the labour market due to illness,

    physical and social malfunctions, or unemployment. They receive economic support by various

    welfare state arrangements. In 2005 OECD claimed that the welfare state arrangements were so

    generous that they were incentives to reduce participation in the labour market, and that Norway

    should cut the support levels. After the financial crisis in 2008 the public share of Norwegian

    GNP and consumption has increased, while other countries have reduced them. Norwegian

    economy still seems to oppose dominant economic theories. Thus we need to understand the

    connections between economic growth and welfare state expenditures.

    3 History of the Nordic model in Norway

    Modernity finally arrives

    Norway was industrialised from the beginning of 1900, much later than for instance England.

    The noblesse or aristocracy was wiped out by the plague in 1342 and concentrations of capital

    dissolved. Thus feudalism was not common like in Sweden and Denmark. New concentrations of

    capital did not develop before the beginning of the 1900s. The modernisation of Norway tookplace within a short frame of time from about 1884 to 1920 and can be described by five

    different processes (Falkum 2008):

    First: the parliamentary system was introduced in 1884. Both the conservative party (Hyre) and

    the social liberal party (Venstre) were established in 1884, while the farmers party

    (Bondepartiet), also conservative, was established in 1921. Common suffrage for men was set in

    1889 and for women in 1913. In 1905 the union with Sweden was dissolved and Hkon the 7th

    was coroneted to be King of Norway.

    Second: Labour, in the sense of paid work, became more common from the end of the 19th

    century. The labour party was established in 1887. A nationwide trade unions associations

    confederation (LO) was settled in 1899. The labour party and the union formed the labour

    movement as a strong alliance that bound them together.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    6/27

    6

    Third: the employers associations national confederationwas organized in 1900 (N.A.F.). They

    had support from the conservative and liberal political parties that governed the state from 1884

    till 1935.

    Fourth: industrialization took speed and expanded significantly from 1905 on. Norsk Hydro

    Aktiekvlstofselskab was established that year and soon became the locomotive in industrial

    development, especially chemical process industries.

    Fifth: The national stock exchange was expanded and reformed in 1911, and capital was

    gathered in financial concentrations that allowed for larger investments. (Falkum 2008)

    Radical ideas and conflicts of interest

    Norway was in a national union with Sweden from 1814 till 1905, and the first labour committee

    was established by the Swedish King Oscar II. The first labour market regulation was a legal act

    in 1892. It introduced a governmental agency that could inspect labour environments and prevent

    unhealthy and dangerous work in manufacturing plants. The committee that developed the act

    had two workers representatives. King Oscar II argued in line with Bismarcks first welfare state

    arrangements that regulations were necessary to ...keep our growing work force on sound and

    reasonable tracks... (Bull 1953:49).

    The first collective agreement was established in 1902, and the first collective agreement that

    covered a complete industry was set in 1907. Governmental labour conflict mediation

    arrangements was launched from 1906 and defined by law from 1915 (Bergh et al 2010).

    The labour party was at its most radical from 1919 when they joined the third communist

    international movement led by Lenin. However, they left the Communist International in 1923

    after controversies with the Russian leaders on sovereignty of national member parties

    (Langfeldt). The labour union was more sceptical to the alliance already in 1919, and the party

    lost about two thirds of their members from then till they left the movement in 1923 (Maurseth).

    Party strategies were changed. The labour party and the trade union now revitalised the strength

    of their alliance. The new and joint strategy was to win political power in parliament by

    democratic means.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    7/27

    7

    The labour union confederation (LO) demanded workers participation and codetermination in the

    management of private companies for the first time in the national wage negotiations in 1918

    (Debes 1918, Falkum 2008). The employers confederation (N.A.F.) characterisedthe demand as

    obnoxious, and the liberal Prime Minister Gunnar Knudsen guaranteed to protect the employers

    private property rights towards revolutionary workers in 1919, if necessary with military forces

    (Bjrnson 1990:550).

    However, the idea of workers participation in company management was already in 1919

    interpreted as an idea of economic democracy that would serve the development of enterprises

    and business in general. Debes (1919) showed that the idea was debated in governmental and

    parliamentary arenas in Germany, England, Finland and America at that time. Even the US

    capitalist J. D. Rockefeller supported the idea according to Debes (ibid:8).

    Basic agreement and the birth of the Nordic model in Norway

    However, economic democracy was not the common interpretation of the idea of workers

    participation at that time. It was mostly anticipated as a threat to private property rights and to

    the administrative prerogative of company owners. The LO demand of codetermination in 1918

    can be seen as the start of more than ten years of heavy labour conflicts. Employers decided

    lockouts, followed by trade union strikes in seemingly endless series (Ousland). In the end of the

    1920s the impact of the all the conflicts was low productivity rates, severely damaged national

    competitiveness and pressure on national economy. Thus the government suggested in 1930 the

    trade unions confederation (LO) and the employers associations confederation (N.A.F.) to join

    a committee on labour peace in order to restore peaceful labour relation, increase productivity

    rates and to meet the severe economic crisis that developed in the beginning of the 1930s. In

    spite of political turbulence, shifting governments from conservative to liberal domination and

    use of military forces towards striking workers in a major industrial conflict in 1931, the work

    peace committee was revitalised in the end of 1934. LO and N.A.F. signed their first basic

    agreement in March 1935. It was to some extent based on texts and experiences in previous

    collective agreements and discussions on legally defined labour regulations.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    8/27

    8

    In 1935 the Labour party won the election for Stortinget (equivalent for Parliament) and entered

    government offices. Except for the World War II (1940 1945) the labour party held the

    government till 1965. New principles of social security legislation were also decided in 1935

    connecting the welfare state offers to the employment rates (Skeie 2003). Employment rates

    would determine national value creation (GNP), tax incomes and thereby levels of welfare

    arrangements, while the welfare arrangements should support participation in labour markets, for

    instance by free and universal education programs, economic housing programs, child care

    support and so on. This is labelled the labour line (arbeidslinja) in welfare politics.

    This starts the development as well as the practice and institutionalisation of the Nordic model in

    Norway:

    1. the Basic Agreements settled rights, obligations and rules to regulate relations between

    employers and unions. It first and foremost defined rules of wage formation, collective

    bargaining and employee participation at the work places as a matter of representative

    democracy.

    2. the labour line was introduced and decided as principle for development of welfare

    arrangements. It connected national productivity and work life directly to the welfare state

    and vice versa: the welfare state arrangements should support productivity.

    The stories of industrial relations developed simultaneously in the Nordic countries. Rules of

    industrial negotiations and the first labour party government were introduced in Denmark in the

    mid 1930s (Due & Madsen 2010). In Sweden labour peace negotiations took place in the early

    1930s, while the basic agreement was settled in 1938 (Lundh 2010). The Scandinavian countries

    also introduced their welfare models about simultaneously. The labour parties were all based on

    social democratic ideas and the unions communicated across the national borders, exchanged

    ideas and experiences and developed policies and politics based on the same ideas and principles

    (Sejersted 2005, Bjrnhaug & Halvorsen 2009).

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    9/27

    9

    4 Three parts sharing power

    The basic agreement is called the constitution of the Norwegian work life (Bergh ed. 2010). It

    defined the workersand unionsrights to participate and codetermine. By asking LO and N.A.F.to solve the disputes, define the industrial relations and thus decide on how to regulate the work

    life in 1930 the government gave away political power to them. They have eagerly tried to keep

    this power to define labour politics without interference from the government or the parliament

    (Falkum 2010). The union and the employers confederation wanted to solve problems by

    agreements and deals between them, while the state tried to introduce labour laws and

    regulations by parliamentary decisions. The government made efforts to withdraw the political

    power from the work life organisations from 1945 on, and had some success with that in the

    1970s. However, labour politics are now mostly decided in collaboration between the two

    confederations and the state in what is called tripartite relations. This system has emerged and

    evolved since the end of World War II. This tripartite collaboration is consensus making and a

    core driver in the interplay of work and welfare and thereby the practice of the Nordic model in

    Norway.

    Developing industrial relations

    Norway was restored after war damages from 1945 on. The union and the employersconfederation made the production agreement (Produksjonsoverenskomsten). Moderate wage

    demands were exchanged with increased investments in more work places and modernisation

    programs. Production committees with union representatives were established in some large

    plants and factories. Management and unions should cooperate for increased productivity. These

    committees were developed into company committees and department committees by a revision

    of the basic agreement in 1966. Workers rights to participate and union rights to codetermine

    was developed and extended in this revision.

    In the negotiations on the revision of the basic agreement in 1966 the employers followed

    liberalist ideas and would give the individual workers more freedom and influence on their own

    individual work situations. They hoped for employee responsibility in business development and

    rise in productivity in return. The union would have more influence for shop stewards and

    members in representative democratic arrangements should be defined in the revised basic

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    10/27

    10

    agreement. They wanted influence on the business strategies and organisation in line with more

    socialist inspired ideas. The revision was made under heavy political pressure. The government

    worked to define the workers rights to participateby political decisions and laws, and not by

    agreement between the work life partners alone. Thus the partners speeded up the process and

    fulfilled the revision in a hurry in order to settle the industrial relations before the political

    system could act. Then both partners got their way: the new agreement stated individual

    workers rights to participate in business development and trade union representatives got their

    right to codetermine. Two democratic principles were introduced simultaneously to the work

    places: individual direct participation and collective representative codetermination. Political

    control over industrial relations was avoided and the social partners kept their political power

    from the process in 1930. (Falkum 2010).

    The 1970s is the only decade where laws dominated over party based agreements. The act of

    limited companies was decided in 1972 and defined rights to demand one third of the company

    board members to be employee representatives. The work environment act from 1977 defined

    Health and safety (H&S) rights, H&S officers and H&S committees to be elected from and by all

    employees, not only union members. Most other rights to have work place democratic

    arrangements are defined by agreements between the labour market actors, even the Including

    Work Life reform since 2001 that try to reduce illness leaves and to make labour available for

    disabled reduce levels of early retirement, and that in essence tries to get people that are

    excluded from the labour market back to work. This is based on an agreement between all

    unions, all employers associations and the state.

    The labour politics in Norway are now based on collaboration between the social partners and

    the state. The power battles are more or less replaced by dialogue, discussions and consensus on

    how to create values and how to spend them. The work life and the development of industrial

    relations have changed the political system.

    Democracy and corporatism

    Norway is governed by democratic political elections for parliament by the citizens. However,

    corporatism has grown Since World War II as well. After the war the labour government wanted

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    11/27

    11

    to establish a national industrial advisory board of coordination with members from the union,

    employers confederation, the government and other important organisations. Also branch

    advisory boards were suggested. The third part of this corporate structure was the production

    councils at work place level. This very hierarchic and firm structure was to give control over

    economic development. All three levels were implemented, but both the national advisory board

    and the branch level boards failed and turned into more or less informal networks. The lowest

    level was developed into company councils that still work as mentioned above. (Falkum 2008).

    Rokkans (1975) famous analysis of corporate pluralism explains how strong interest groups

    participate and influence the political democratic system through numerous public councils,

    boards and committees that are set up to investigate, explore, describe and advice governmental

    agencies. Participation in the corporative system gives political influence and power that exceeds

    the power of the ordinary citizens by far. As Rokkan (1975) concluded: votes count, but

    resources decide. The corporative arrangements are developed a lot since the 1960s and are in

    use in most sectors and fields of politics. This dual system of democratic and corporate

    arrangements is a basic condition for tripartite relations. The wage formation process is an

    illustrative case.

    Tripartite wage formation

    LO, NHO (the modernised employers associations confederation, earlier N.A.F.) and the

    government, no matter party in office, meet informally at the Prime Ministers office every

    spring to discuss the possibilities and challenges in the annual wage negotiations. Normally they

    will come to a shared understanding of sustainable levels.

    To create such shared understanding of the economic situation is also the aim of Council of

    (Teknisk Beregningsutvalg) headed by a high rank officer in ministry of finance and with

    members from LO, NHO, the government and researchers. They set up a public document that

    describes the economic values to be negotiated. The conclusions in the report is discussed and

    agreed upon before publishing. By agreeing on how to interpret the economic situation the

    negotiations will principally concentrate on LO demands and NHO offers

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    12/27

    12

    LO and NHO will base their negotiations on this report. They will discuss alternative solutions

    and try to sort the opposing interests in give and take balances that can be supported by the union

    members in the end. It is always the wages in the most competitive industries that are negotiated

    first. The result of this negotiation sets the levels for all the later negotiations among all unions

    and employers associations. The intention is to avoid rises that will give increase in prices and

    inflation.

    Sometimes the state plays a major role in the wage formation. After the crisis in economy in

    1986/1987 the parliament passed a wage law that forbid rise in wages above specific levels,

    especially for high educated and high waged groups. This was done to support the national

    economy. The law was withdrawn the next year, but it was the start of a compression of wage

    levels in Norway. Still today academic and high educated employees have lower wages than in

    other comparable countries. Highly educated labour is cheap, while the low educated work force

    is quite expensive in Norway compared to other countries in Europe. Thus it is profitable to

    establish technological advanced production in Norway compared to neighbour countries, and

    quite unprofitable to establish or run simple and low technology production. This has reduced

    numbers of low technology enterprises and increased production of commodities and services

    that needs educated staff.

    This logic has been supported by education programs. In times of economic downturns the

    government has increased student numbers and arrangements for tertiary education. The

    education system is held to be the most successful part of the Norwegian welfare arrangements

    by politicians (Steen 1999).

    In the early 1990s the labour party introduced what they called the Solidarity alternative for the

    wage formation. Instead of high rises in wages the state introduced new welfare arrangements

    like early retirement programs, lifelong learning programs and policies for developing new work

    places. Tax rates, sick leave compensation and pension program may be discussed and play a

    role in the negotiations. What the employers gained from moderate union wage demands was

    supposed to be invested in new work places. This program was developed and agreed upon by all

    the political parties in the parliament and the social work life partners. The Including work life

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    13/27

    13

    program in 2001 is a further development of the logics of the Solidarity alternative and signed by

    the same actors.

    In these ways the wage formation connects the price of labour directly to the public welfare

    programs. Business and value creation is supported by welfare state politics. Economy and

    politics are interwoven and directly interconnected. In this respect the welfare state is not only to

    be defined as public expenditures. There are arguments to define the welfare state arrangements

    as investments in a sustainable economy. This perspective will be further outlined in the final

    discussion.

    Labour conflicts

    The wage formation processes is where Norwegian labour actions can take place. If the social

    partners do not agree they have to contact the neutral and independent public mediator

    (Riksmeklingsmannen) appointed by the government since 1906. The negotiations then continue

    through the mediator who will try to find solutions that ends the conflicts of interest. This has to

    be reached within 48 hours, if not there will be strike, and the union will select a sample of work

    places to start the strike. The partners can approach each other via the public mediator in order to

    end the strike and find solution that is agreed.

    If the partners reach agreement the solution has to be voted over by all the union members. There

    are some examples that such solutions are turned down by the voting members, and a strike is

    then implemented.

    Strikes and labour conflicts may be stopped by a governmental wage council, normally

    legitimated when a strike may endanger health and life for a third part, for instance patients in

    hospitals under nurse strikes.

    Normally 3 15 strikes take place annually. They are all results of disagreement during wage

    negotiations. It is not allowed to strike or implement lockouts during the period of the collective

    bargained agreement. The last lock out from NHO members was in 1986. Political strikes are not

    allowed. Norwegian work life is quite peaceful compared to for instance Denmark and France

    that have more than 1000 labour conflicts some years. The public mediator, the labour court and

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    14/27

    14

    the different tripartite councils all contribute to peaceful solving of opposing interests and

    consensus among the social partners.

    5 Sustainability of the work life

    high road development

    The compressed wage levels, the many welfare arrangements and the direct connection between

    production and welfare arrangements have over the years made the work life flexible and

    dynamic.

    Organisational change and enterprise development

    There are weak rules on collective dismissals in labour laws and agreements, while the

    protection towards individual dismissals is in line with other European countries. Thus it is quite

    easy to downsize or close down enterprises compared to most European countries. If the

    employer can argue and prove that major organisational changes have to be implemented to save

    the business, there are minimal obstacles to do so. Normally the employer will have to pay the

    employees three months wages as compensation. Unemployment after those three months will

    give the workers economic support by the social security system. However, most employers that

    downsize will normally give compensations that exceed these standards pretty much.

    Downsizing, closing down work places or moving business to low cost countries will often be

    opposed by unions, politicians and sometimes result in massive protest marches, but they will

    nevertheless be implemented as planned (Falkum 2008). There are only few cases where such

    plans have been stopped, and in those few cases the union at the work place have come up with

    some kind of offer to contribute to the enterprise business.

    Norwegian companies are developed and changed in dynamic ways. They may move across

    branches, enter new businesses, change production methods or implement new technologies

    quite easily. This is accepted as normal also by the unions. A former second head of LO

    explained why they never demand strong rules towards collective dismissals in this way:

    We always thought it more important to create new and modern work places than to keep the

    old ones going by all means.(Jan Balstad, former head of LO)

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    15/27

    15

    A survey in a recent random sample drawn from the public national employers employee

    register we found that 29 percent of Norwegian employees had shifted job during the last two

    years (Falkum et al 2009). In 1993 the equivalent figure was 21 percent (Salvanes 2003). The

    Norwegian employees are mobile and flexible, adapt to work place development and labour

    markets and in these ways contribute to the structural and functional flexibility needed in

    globalising economies. The mobility and flexibility seem to be growing, as it has increased from

    1993 to 2009. However, some industries and branches increase the amount of part time labour in

    recent years, mostly in service sectors and especially in public health care and shopping malls.

    Standing (2010) shows that precarious work increases in the globalizing economies. That seems

    to drab even highly regulated work lives like the Norwegian to some extent.

    The oil and gas industry an example of high road development

    Norwegian economy has depended on export of raw materials from mining, woods and fishery.

    The production of commodities has concentrated on low degrees of fabrication like aluminium

    and artificial fertilizers. Knowledge of methods and technologies has been imported to some

    extent. The oil and gas production is an exception.

    The oil and gas fields were discovered in the North Sea in the 1960s. Politicians proposed that

    multinational oil companies should operate the fields and that the national economy should only

    receive bargained incomes. Some other politicians opposed to that and defined the explorations

    and field operations to be national tasks. A state owned oil company, Statoil, was established in

    1972 in order to handle the national oil and gas properties and to develop the industry. Several

    other nations nationalised their oil reservoirs in this period (Ryggvik ).

    The nationalisation made it necessary to develop knowledge, technologies and supply chains

    needed. Natural and technological sciences got strong supports and tertiary education systems

    like universities and business schools oriented towards oil exploration, production and economy.

    Not only those employed in oil industry, but many other industries were affected.

    Ship yards turned from building ordinary ships to production of oil rigs, supply ships and highly

    specialized boats need for very special North Sea operations. During the last decade they have

    outsourced the building of shells to low cost production sites abroad, and towing them home to

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    16/27

    16

    do the most advanced labour and technical installations by themselves. Ship building in Norway

    is now based on innovative design, engineering expertise and high competence vocational

    training. Norway has now leading competence and experience in deep water oil production.

    Extreme technology makes it possible to drill and produce at 3000 meters depths with all

    operations executed in on shore installations and without any diving.

    Statoil was merged with the other national industrial actor, the Hydro oil & gas division in 2006.

    This was part of a restructuring of national industrial interests. The merger should give Statoil

    the capacities and competences needed to become a recognized operator on international oil

    fields. Results so far are shares in Russian and Brasilian oil and gas fields.

    In a small country like Norway it is hard to find parts of the society that are completely

    untouched by the national oil production. It is an example of high road development:

    opportunities are used to develop knowledge and competencies in constant innovative

    development in several areas.

    The nationalisation of the oil industry was done in harmony with core ideas in the Nordic model:

    shared efforts should result in fair distribution of results. The high road development in the oil

    and oil related industries was conditioned by the public education system, public research and

    development funding and collaboration and consensus between the social partners. The funding

    of oil incomes since the late 1990s was established to carry increasing welfare future

    expenditures. The oil politics in Norway is in line with the intentions of the Nordic model.

    Status of work place democracy

    The survey (Falkum et al 2009) was made to mirror the state of work place democracy. A

    random sample of 8000 was drawn from the national employee/employer register. We had 3362

    answers. This net sample was tested if representative along key dimensions like gender, age,

    education, sectors, industries, location and number of employees at the work places. Work places

    with 10 employees or less was left out, but we still have some of the smallest workplaces in the

    sample since some of them were reduced after the data was obtained in the national register. We

    lack data from the informal sector and companies that are not represented in the register.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    17/27

    17

    The survey was obtained in the spring 2009 when the forecasts about unemployment rates were

    at the darkest. 91 percent of the employers and 93 percent of employees supports the labour

    regulations as the claim the labour laws, the basic agreements and the collective bargaining to be

    very important to recognize, follow and obey by all actors in the labour market. We interpret this

    to express strong support to the national work life regime.

    TABLE 1 THE RESPONDENTS EVALUATION OF THEIR OWN INFLUENCE ON OWN WORK SITUATION, WORKORGANIZATION AND GOVERNING AND RUNNING OF BUSINESS AFTER WORK PLACE POSITIONS.AVERAGE SCORE ON

    A SCALE WHERE 1=LITTLE INFLUENCE AND 5=MUCH INFLUENCE

    Respondents position Own work

    situation

    Work

    organisation

    Governing and

    organisation

    N

    Manager 4,7 4,0 3,6 542-427

    Shop steward 4,4 3,5 2,7 782-585

    H&S officer 4,5 3,5 2,7 459-347

    Ordinary employee 4,3 3,4 2,3 2493-1789

    Total average 4,4 3,5 2,6 3071-2244

    The variables Influence on own work situation is an index of three di fferent variables in the

    survey. Influence on work organization is likewise put together with four different variables on

    this issue. In on governing and organization consist of alltogether 12 related variables in the

    survey. The use of indexes makes the analyses more robust towards coincidences.

    The table shows that the respondents perceive their influence on their own work situation as very

    high. The liberalist and managerial intention of work place democracy as individual influence on

    own work situation, or autonomy, seem to be highly fulfilled. Managers have some more

    autonomy than the other groups, as expected, but the differences are small. The average

    influence on the organization of work at the work place is less than influence on individual work

    situation, but still on the positive side of the median (3 on the scale from 1 5). Managers have

    more influence than the others, but organization of work is a managerial task and the difference

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    18/27

    18

    is expected. The respondents perceptions of their influence on governing and organisation of the

    enterprise are much lower than the other two. On one hand this is what unions and shop stewards

    are supposed to influence in collaborative representative councils, and the single employee

    influence on this is supposed to be lower than their influence on work organisation and own

    work situation. However, we expected the shop stewards and H&S officers to have more

    influence than they report in the survey. The representative democracy seems to have potential

    for improvements. The survey also shows that to have collective bargaining, trade unions and

    shop stewards improves the practice of democratic work place arrangements.

    FIGURE 1 DEMOCRATIC ARRANGEMENTS AT PLACE IN WORK PLACES WITH AND WITHOUT UNIONS (N=3262

    PERCENT)

    This figure shows that a large majority of work places with union members have established

    democratic arrangements according to laws and agreements. A surprising amount of work places

    without unions have also established such arrangements. We have interpreted this as an

    indication of institutionalization: the labour regulations have been established for so long that

    they have become work life norms that influence on employers and employees behavior despite

    formal approvals of unions, collective bargaining or basic agreements.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    19/27

    19

    Work place changes

    If the Nordic model works according to its intentions it should help work places to adapt to

    market situations and help business development. The survey shows how the Norwegianemployees are exposed to work place changes and how they react to that. These are figures of

    major changes during the two last years.

    29 percent of the respondents got new CEO/Top managers

    19 percent was in a work place that was merged with another enterprise

    14 percent was transferred to another organisation unit

    11 percent got new owners and

    7 percent worked in a unit that was outsourced

    These figures describe the level of change in the Norwegian work places. It seems quite

    turbulent, but comparable data from other countries are needed to make more subtle analyses. On

    the other hand it is interesting to see how employees react to change. We asked the question in

    the figure heading below.

    FIGURE 2HOW DID YOU REACT TO THE IMPLEMENTATION OF THE LAST CHANGE DECIDED BY MANAGEMENT AND

    THAT YOU DISAGREED IN?(N= 968,PERCENTS)

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    20/27

    20

    Almost half of the respondents would support the change that they were against. 32 percent

    would react indifferently while 22 percent would oppose the managerial decision by resistance to

    change. A majority of 77 percent would actively or passively support the change process despite

    disagreement. This finding can indicate that also individual participants in the Norwegian work

    life are most likely to avoid conflicts. Loyalty is more likely than voice or exit on individual

    levels.

    6 Institutionalisation of the Nordic hybridThe empirical findings will be discussed in the institutional theoretic framework

    From conflicts to regulations

    The first element in institutionalisation theory was the establishment of rules to regulate relations

    and actions. Labour regulating rules was developed from 1885 on and culminated with the basic

    agreement in 1935 as a first stage of institutionalisations. Conflicts and conflict arenas were

    calmed down and replaced by dialogue, exchange of information, negotiations and bargaining.

    The labour movement was an alliance of the trade union and the labour party. On the other side

    the liberal and conservative state formed an alliance with the employersassociations. Many of

    the rules were introduced to settle ways to handle conflicts and balance out differing interests

    more peacefully: laws to reduce unreasonable exploitation of workers, establishment of conflict

    mediators and labour court, agreements on collective bargaining, wage formation and working

    conditions. Regulation by rules finally succeeded in 1935.

    From rules to norms

    The rules and regulatory mechanisms were developed further from 1945 till the early 1980, and

    are still adjusted or modified from time to time. By the beginning of the 1980s most employers

    and employee rights are defined and formally agreed and decided. Most of them were practiced

    from the 1960s and forwards, and they were slowly internalised as norms that guided actions and

    work life behaviour. The industrial relations showed to be reliable. The social partners could

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    21/27

    21

    trust each other to an extent that made it possible to predict actions and reactions in different

    situations that might occur. These are the basic functions of social norms. They developed slowly

    by dialogues, incidents, events and incidental in incremental ways. This development was not

    planned or decided. It emerged and evolved.

    From norms to truth regimes

    The third part of the institutional perspective was cognitive: the development of shared

    understandings of reality. There were many elements implemented to prevent conflicts and press

    the social partners towards consensus: the labour court, the public mediator, the wage formation

    council, the formal wage formation procedures and the governmental welfare contributions to

    agreements and balance of originally differing interests. Even conflicting interests became

    predictable and possible to prevent in this system. Mutual trust, respect and conflict solving

    procedures were finally established as a shared understanding of how the industrial relations

    work and are connected to the various welfare arrangements. Norms may develop into a truth

    regime that governs the perceptions and interpretation of almost any occurring situation:

    Whatever happens, society will know how to handle it. The findings from the work life survey

    confirm this impression to some extent. Norwegian work life seems to be dominated by rules and

    regulations, norms and social identifications and by understandings of realities that are shared by

    all the actors.

    From truth regimes to dynamic economy

    This truth regime makes the rules for actions to be taken and behavioural procedures:

    that unions and employers must collaborate,

    that shop stewards must codetermine,

    that individual employers must participate

    that the government will contribute to the solving of problems and

    that the welfare arrangements are there when the work life fails

    Simultaneously this regime defines and is the key to understand the appointed dynamics and the

    opportunities for high road development. The dynamics of economy is embedded in well defined

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    22/27

    22

    industrial relations, organisational structures and human behaviour. Hence the Nordic model is a

    competitive advantage in global economies.

    The hybrid Nordic model

    The Nordic model was never a fixed plot. It was developed under influence of many differing

    directions. It is a true hybrid in the sense that it combines opposing ideas and interests in an

    almost Hegelian way: thesis and antithesis are developed into synthesis in various respects as the

    opposing ideas, understandings and interests are successively played out by the actors as

    windows of opportunity incidentally pass by. These synthesis and combinations of ideas forms

    the Nordic model as characteristics of the social, political and economic system emerge in

    society by events and incidents over most of the last century. It ends up in a steadily firmer

    structure that eventually guides decision making, implementation and governance in work life,

    welfare state and society. The figure below presents this development from contradictions and

    conflicts to consensus on synthesis.

    FIGURE 3THE COMBINATION OF OPPOSING IDEAS IN THE NORDIC MODEL

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    23/27

    23

    The first work life conflicts developed in some small production plants already in the end of

    1800s. Opposing interests of labour and capital developed to contradictions that were almost

    antagonist in 1918. The social partners had organised and played out their differences especiallyduring the 1920s. This ended in the basic agreement, employers accept of the union as economic

    counterpart, labour movements accept of the private property rights and liberal parties accept of

    the labour party as a legitimate player in the parliamentary system. The law of social security

    was introduced to provide economic aid to those in need, but was not accepted by the

    conservative party until the principle was to support the work life as well. These are the synthesis

    developed from labour and capital contradictions, and they formed the basic rules that regulate

    the work life.

    This body of regulations implemented the political system for decision making. The labour

    movement had to leave the socialist refusal of private property rights in order to be a legitimate

    parliamentary actor. Social democracy combined some of the values and analysis in socialism

    with the methods of political decision making in liberalism. This is the basic synthesis of liberal

    thesis and socialist antithesis along the line. New meanings and understandings of reality was

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    24/27

    24

    derived from the agreements on how to regulate and end labour conflicts. This social democratic

    pragmatism came to dominate politic and the complete society to the end of the 1960s.

    The third contradiction is between plan economy VS market capitalism after WWII. The social

    democratic government implemented heavy price and production restrictions and intended to

    implement a soft socialisation of enterprises in a kind of states capitalism (Bergh 198 ). The US

    Marshall plan demanded removal of these regulations. The government gave way for

    liberalisation of markets in order to have the economic benefits of the plan, and thereby accepted

    capitalist production systems in 1948 (Bergh 2009). The liberalist thesis became the synthesis

    while the socialisation policies, Lex Brofoss, were left behind.

    The fourth synthesis is tripartite decision making: the three part collaboration between the state

    and the social partners derive from democratic VS corporative methods. Rokkans pluralist

    corporatism is the scientific synthesis of the same contradiction.

    The last synthesis combines the productivity thesis with welfare state ideas. According to

    economic theory the welfare state arrangements forms a body of antithesis towards the

    productivity thesis when they become too generous, but the level that turns welfare policies to

    contradicting antithesis is dubious and blurry. Norway offers a case where that line is drawn

    much longer than economic theories recommend. This is where all the other synthesis come

    together in one that now guides economy, politics and social life. To discuss the welfare state

    arrangements as investments may help us out of the confusion.

    The Nordic model as investment scheme

    The previous outline has pointed to developed praxis in Norway in frame of the Nordic model.

    The interconnections of work life and the welfare state, of politics and economy and labour and

    capital make it relevant to identify and discuss the Nordic model as an investment scheme. We

    can identify investors, their investments and the returns of investments on all levels in the work

    life. The welfare state compares to a bank or an investment fund that control, expand and provide

    resources in shared manners according to needs. So far this is a sketch for further discussions.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    25/27

    25

    TABLE 2INVESTMENTS AND PROVIDED RETURNS

    Individual investment Provided returns

    labour autonomy, good work environment

    taxes free education and services, pensions

    union participation rights, predictable economy, influence

    enterprise development participation job improvements, personal development

    Work place investments Provided returns

    economic capital autonomous work force, cheap competencies

    taxes educated work force, welfare state supportemployers association member network, employer rights, political influence

    tripartite industrial relations predictable ecomomy, high road development

    union collaboration support for agreed development

    National investments Provided returns

    welfare expenditures high road development

    tripartite arrangements stable, predictable and growing economy(governmental investment funds future wealth for generations to come)

    This table presents an analysis of the Nordic model as it is played out in Norway. It may

    represent a path for new perspectives and theories in labour and welfare research. In this

    perspective the Nordic model becomes a context for economic growth, not a virtually hopeless

    and helpless insect. The hybrid Nordic model combines economy and politics as two aspects of

    the same intentions, decisions and implementation that govern of the society. That is what makes

    an investment perspective relevant, and simultaneously confuses liberal economic theories based

    on the ancient sharp distinctions between politics and economy.

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    26/27

    26

    References

    Bergh, T. (red.) (1983) Deltakerdemokratiet. Demokrati og samfunnsstyring.Oslo: Universitetsforlaget

    Bergh. T. (red.) (2010)Avtalt spill. Hovedavtalen 75 r. Oslo: LO/NHO

    Bergh, Trond (2009): Kollektiv fornuft. LOs historie Bind 3 1969 2009. Oslo:Pax

    Bjrnson, . (1990) P klassekampens grunn (19001920). Arbeiderbevegelsens historie i Norge.Oslo:

    Tiden Norsk Forlag A/S

    Bull, E. (1953)Arbeidervern gjennom 60 r. Utgitt av Statens arbeidstilsyn, Oslo: Tiden Norsk forlag

    Bjrnhaug, Inger & Terje Halvorsen (2009): LOs Historie. Medlemsmakt og samfunnsansvar. Bind 2 1935

    1969, Oslo:Pax

    Debes, I. (1919) konomisk demokrati. Arbeidernes andel i bedriftsledelsen. Kristiania: Steenske Forlag

    Due, J., J. S. Madsen (2010) Septemberforliget 1899 og udviklingen av den danske aftalemodell, I Bergh.

    T. (red.) (2010)Avtalt spill. Hovedavtalen 75 r. Oslo: LO/NHO

    Falkum, E. (2008) Makt og opposisjon i norsk arbeidsliv. Dr avhandling, UiO. Fafo-rapport 2008: 31

    Falkum, E., I. M. Hagen, S. C. Trygstad (2009) Bedriftsdemokratiets tilstand. Fafo-rapport 2009:35

    Falkum, E. (2010) Plan A, men del B. Hovedavtalen i det politisk konomiske landskapet. I Bergh, T. (red)

    (2010)Avtalt spill. Hovedavtalen 75 r. Oslo: LO/NHO

    Foucault, M. (1982) The subject and power. I H.L. Dreyfus and P. Rabinow (eds.) Michel Foucault: beyond

    structuralism and hermeneutics. Brighton: Harvester, 208226

    Hernes, G. (1975) Makt og avmakt, Oslo: Universitetsforlaget

    Kuhnle, S. (1983) Velferdsstatens utvikling. Norge I komparativt perspektiv. Bergen: Universitetsforlaget

    Kuhnle, S. (ed.) (2000) Survival of the European Welfare state. London: Routledge

    Langfeldt, K. (1961) Moskvatesene i norsk politikk. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget

    Lundh, C. (2010) Saltsjbadsavtalet och arbetsfreden. I Bergh. T. (red.) (2010) Avtalt spill. Hovedavtalen

    75 r. Oslo: LO/NHO

    March, J. G. & J. P. Olsen (1995) Democratic Governance, New York: The Free Press, A division of Simon

    & Schuster Inc.

    Maurseth, P. (1987) Gjennom kriser til makt (1920 1935). Arbeiderbevegelsens historie i Norge.Oslo:

    Tiden Norsk Forlag

  • 8/13/2019 efa-paper-101213

    27/27

    27

    Mayhew, L. H. ed. (1982) Introduction, in Parsons, T. Talcott Parsons on Institutions and Social Evolution,

    The Heritage of Sociology, Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press

    Ousland, G. (1949) De store kampra: 1921 1931. Oslo: Arbeidernes faglige landsorganisasjon i Norge

    Parsons, T. (1982) Talcott Parsons on Institutions and Social Evolution, The Heritage of Sociology,

    (Mayhew, L.H. (ed.)) Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press

    Rokkan, S. (1975) Votes count, resources decide. Refleksjoner over territorialitet versus funksjonalitet I

    norsk og europeisk politick. I Makt og motiv. Et festskrift til jens Arup Seip, Oslo: Gyldendal

    Scott, W. R. (1995) Institutions and Organizations, Thousand Oaks, London, New Dehli: Sage

    Publications

    Steen, R. (1999) Underveis. Det 21. rhundrets velferdssamfunn. Oslo: Fafo-Tiden

    Sejersted, F. (2005) Sosialdemokratiets tidsalder. Norge og Sverige i det 20. rhundre, Oslo: Pax Forlag as

    Schmitter, P. C. (1974) Still the century of corporatism?, i Pike, F. & T. Strich, ed. (1974) The New

    Corporatism, social-political structures in the Iberian world, Notre Dame: University of Notre

    Dame Press

    Schmitter, P. C. & G. Lehmbruch (1979) Trends Towards Corporatist Intermediation. Beverly

    Hills/London: Sage Publications

    Skeie, J. (2003) Velferdsstaten og flukten fra markedet, i Benum, E. et al. (2003) Den mangfoldige

    velferden, Festskrift til Anne Lise Seip, Oslo:Gyldendal

    Standing, G. (2010) Work after globalisation. Building occupational citizenship. Cheltenham UK: Edward

    Elgar

    Stensaker, I, H. Colman, J. Tharaldsen eds. (2011 (in print)) Merger of Equals?Oslo: Fagbokforlaget

    Trist, E. L., G. W. Higgin, H. Murray, A. B. Pollock (1963) Organizational Choice: capabilities of groups at

    the coal face under changing technologies, London: Tavistock Publications

    Thorsrud, E. & F. E. Emery (1970) Mot en ny bedriftsorganisasjon, Eksperimenter i industrielt demokrati,

    Fra Samarbeidsprosjektet LO/NAF, Oslo: Tanum

    yen. E. (19