4
www.thesolutionsjournal.org | July-August 2016 | Solutions  | 27 Perspectives Bush, S.R. (2016). Reversing the Burden of Sustainable Aquaculture. Solutions 7(4): 27–30. https://thesolutionsjournal.com/article/reversing-the-burden-of-sustainable-aquaculture/ I magine a fish farmer in a develop- ing country, with poor literacy and  minimal capital, having to comply  with international sustainability  standards in order to sell their fish.  Then, imagine they have not been  involved in setting these standards and  in fact, no one came to consult them  on what makes their farms sustain- able or not. However, to comply with  these standards and maintain market  access, they will need to make changes  to how they manage water quality,  biodiversity, and demonstrate good  labor practices. In the short term,  these changes will directly affect their  livelihoods and incomes through  increased costs and efforts, while any  benefits from sustainability remains a  long-term and uncertain proposition.  For such farmers, the biggest irony  is that buyers requiring compliance  to sustainability standards are also  dependent on their fish as one of the  most important meat proteins for  global food and nutrition security.  Given this dependence, demonstrat- ing compliance with these standards  might seem like a disproportionate  burden. In Asia, export markets must seem  like a double-edged sword to the  more than 16 million smallholder  fish farmers in the most productive  aquaculture region of the world. 1 On the one hand, farmers in major  production regions like Asia and many  other parts of South America and West  Africa make an increasingly important  contribution to a healthier and more  sustainable source of animal protein  than other meat products in major  export markets. 2 Accessing export  markets also offer the opportunity  to charge higher prices and therefore  increase incomes. But on the other  hand, the global boom in aquaculture  production, with production now  equivalent to ‘capture fisheries’ pro- duction, 3 has led to increased concern  for NGOs, consumers, and govern- ments about environmental and social  impacts. This has resulted in greater  surveillance over production through  audited compliance to voluntary  sustainability standards. As many supermarkets have  pledged to only purchase sustainably  certified seafood, including fish from  aquaculture, a core group of standards  have emerged as de facto barriers to  market access. 4 Arguably the two most  dominant standards have also taken  on a divided geography between the  two largest importing markets in the  world. The Aquaculture Stewardship  Council (ASC) standards are more  recognized in Europe, while the  Global Aquaculture Alliance (GAA) is  dominant in the US. More than ever  before, access to these export markets  requires producers to demonstrate  their sustainability through respective  certification from these organizations. It is commonly assumed by  academics, NGOs, and policy makers  alike that the burden of proving that  compliance to sustainability stan- dards, like any other legal or market  requirement, lies with producers.  Indeed, this assumption is the very  basis of voluntary certification; farm- ers should actively demonstrate their  ‘good’ production practices. But global- ized seafood markets also mean that  producers are far from one homog- enous group. Over 85 percent of the  volume of fish traded to Organization  for Economic Co-operation and  Development (OECD) countries comes  from the developing world. 3 Shifting  the burden of proof to producers  in developing countries does not  consider the capacity of individual  producers to demonstrate compliance  with international standards. Major buyers of seafood, includ- ing both wholesale importers and  Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquaculture by Simon R. Bush Simon Bush Small-scale pangasius fingerling nursery in An Giang province, Vietnam.

Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquaculture

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Perspective, Volume 7, Issue 4

Citation preview

Page 1: Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquaculture

www.thesolutionsjournal.org  |  July-August 2016  |  Solutions  |  27

Perspectives

Bush, S.R. (2016). Reversing the Burden of Sustainable Aquaculture. Solutions 7(4): 27–30.

https://thesolutionsjournal.com/article/reversing-the-burden-of-sustainable-aquaculture/

Imagine a fish farmer in a develop-ing country, with poor literacy and 

minimal capital, having to comply with international sustainability standards in order to sell their fish. Then, imagine they have not been involved in setting these standards and in fact, no one came to consult them on what makes their farms sustain-able or not. However, to comply with these standards and maintain market access, they will need to make changes to how they manage water quality, biodiversity, and demonstrate good labor practices. In the short term, these changes will directly affect their livelihoods and incomes through increased costs and efforts, while any benefits from sustainability remains a long-term and uncertain proposition. For such farmers, the biggest irony is that buyers requiring compliance to sustainability standards are also dependent on their fish as one of the 

most important meat proteins for global food and nutrition security. Given this dependence, demonstrat-ing compliance with these standards might seem like a disproportionate burden.

In Asia, export markets must seem like a double-edged sword to the more than 16 million smallholder fish farmers in the most productive aquaculture region of the world.1 On the one hand, farmers in major production regions like Asia and many other parts of South America and West Africa make an increasingly important contribution to a healthier and more sustainable source of animal protein than other meat products in major export markets.2 Accessing export markets also offer the opportunity to charge higher prices and therefore increase incomes. But on the other hand, the global boom in aquaculture production, with production now 

equivalent to ‘capture fisheries’ pro-duction,3 has led to increased concern for NGOs, consumers, and govern-ments about environmental and social impacts. This has resulted in greater surveillance over production through audited compliance to voluntary sustainability standards.

As many supermarkets have pledged to only purchase sustainably certified seafood, including fish from aquaculture, a core group of standards have emerged as de facto barriers to market access.4 Arguably the two most dominant standards have also taken on a divided geography between the two largest importing markets in the world. The Aquaculture Stewardship Council (ASC) standards are more recognized in Europe, while the Global Aquaculture Alliance (GAA) is dominant in the US. More than ever before, access to these export markets requires producers to demonstrate their sustainability through respective certification from these organizations.

It is commonly assumed by academics, NGOs, and policy makers alike that the burden of proving that compliance to sustainability stan-dards, like any other legal or market requirement, lies with producers. Indeed, this assumption is the very basis of voluntary certification; farm-ers should actively demonstrate their ‘good’ production practices. But global-ized seafood markets also mean that producers are far from one homog-enous group. Over 85 percent of the volume of fish traded to Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries comes from the developing world.3 Shifting the burden of proof to producers in developing countries does not consider the capacity of individual producers to demonstrate compliance with international standards.

Major buyers of seafood, includ-ing both wholesale importers and 

Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquacultureby Simon R. Bush

Simon Bush Small-scale pangasius fingerling nursery in An Giang province, Vietnam.

Page 2: Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquaculture

28  |  Solutions  |  July-August 2016  |  www.thesolutionsjournal.org

Perspectives

retailers, are also able to dictate the terms of trade to their suppliers. Not only do they demand sustainable seafood, they establish contracts in order to deliver high volumes with the lowest possible unit cost. It remains unclear whether any market premiums are observed for those products certified, and even less clar-ity as to whether these are passed up the chain to producers.5,6 Instead, it is the cost of certification that is pushed back up the chain to producers, placing a disproportionate burden on smallholders. In classical Marxist terms, by instituting diminishing returns to their suppliers these lead firms risk undermining the very pro-ducers upon whom their own supply of seafood is based.

One way to overcome this is to reverse the burden of proof, so that it is not the 117 million fish farmers worldwide that need to demonstrate sustainability,7 but instead the buyers and retailers who receive a dispropor-tionate benefit from their production. But what would this look like?

A first step could be to shift the demonstration of sustainability compliance down the chain from producers to buyers. This would mean that standards become a tool for retailers and importers rather than for producers. Instead of setting environmental and social metrics at the farm level,these standards would, for instance, regulate how retailers support producers and others in their supply chains to improve their sustainability performance and demonstrate legal compliance. Under such a system, top–down regulation of producers would give way to what has been termed by Ivarsson and Alvstam as a ‘developmental’ mode of chain governance.8 Retailers would be certified based on a requisite level of technological and organizational assistance, co-innovation, developing 

human capacity, and financial and administrative advice, all aimed at supporting environmental and social performance.

Such a developmental approach to sustainable seafood would remain market based to the extent that com-panies would be recognized for the support they provide rather than the individual products on their shelves. Competition to be the greenest grocer on the high street would therefore still drive investment in sustainability.

The sustainability impacts of cer-tifying retail support to aquaculture improvement are potentially greater than in current producer oriented standards. Voluntary farm-based standards are most commonly taken up by producers who already exhibit a degree of compliance.9 But by inadvertently cherry-picking better performers, the degree of overall improvement across the industry is limited. Recognizing and promoting continuous improvement towards sustainability would increase the involvement of less well-performing producers who cannot currently comply with high-level ASC or GAA standards. Such an inclusive approach is of key importance, because it is with these aquaculture producers where the greatest overall sustainability gains are still to be made.

In practice, retailers are already making investments in currently ‘un-certifiable’ producers through aquaculture improvement projects (so called AIPs). This support comes in many forms, including paying for direct support for improved farm prac-tices like water purification, training on stocking, and pharmaceutical use as well as paying for consultants to assist with the paperwork required to dem-onstrate improvement.10 But unlike product-based certification, which provides market recognition through eco-labelling, retailers receive very 

little recognition for these more direct and in many cases locally engaged forms of support they provide. They are limited in making sustainability claims around their support because there is no standardization of what makes a credible and effective aquacul-ture improvement project.11 Retailers therefore run the risk of not being able to make claims in the market place because there is no third party substan-tiating the support they are providing to suppliers. It is here that retail level certification would fill the gap by pro-viding a system of verification, market recognition, and ultimately greater incentives for further investment in smallholder support.

Retail level certification could expand the overall scope of impact that market-based sustainability approaches can have on the aquacul-ture industry and beyond. Currently, the expansion of farm-level certifica-tion is limited by the willingness and capacity of each producer who applies for certification.4 If this farm-level mode of certification is removed, so too is an important barrier to the expansion of certified sustainability practices. Making retailers responsible for demonstrating a developmental mode of sustainability support could also lead to considerable gains in sustainability because the cost, and therefore the choice to improve, is no longer dispersed across many producers.

Shifting the cost of certification down the value chain would also put pressure on retailers and suppliers to search for innovative and more effi-cient forms of organizing aquaculture sustainability. One outcome would be the need for greater efficiencies for retailers to deliver support to individual producers beyond the farm through, for example, cooperative forms of management. Cooperative management of aquaculture has 

Page 3: Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquaculture

www.thesolutionsjournal.org  |  July-August 2016  |  Solutions  |  29

Perspectives

been met with mixed success, largely because of poor internal capacity, weak state support, and the complex-ity of environmental and health issues such as water quality and disease.12 A developmental approach with buyer investment may prove more successful than current cooperative approaches because it would link the level and quality of producer support to the reputation and market demand of buyers. Because buyers would still be driven by environmental outcomes, the cooperatives they support may also engage in ecosystem or area-based forms of management, and in doing so, link farm-level practices to issues like water quality that extend well beyond the boundaries of a single farm.13

More coordinated support and organization of producers by buyers could also lead to improved risk management in the industry. By moving certification beyond the farm 

level and creating contractual sup-port from buyers in export markets, opportunities for insurance and new forms of financing may also emerge. Such opportunities would be transformative in the aquaculture sector in developing countries given the high degree of production risk experienced by producers and the associated lack of formal insurance and finance opportunities.1 The outcome would be two-fold: produc-ers would benefit from receiving the necessary capacity to reduce produc-tion risk and sustainably intensify production, while buyers would benefit from a more stable supply of sustainably produced fish.

Would such a system need new certification schemes beyond the ASC and GAA? Not necessarily. The goal of these certification schemes is to assure responsible aquaculture production. While this goal would 

remain the same, new standards would be required that focus on verifying that a developmental-chain approach like AIPs are leading to real and con-tinual improvements in aquaculture production. However, new models of certification or other forms of verifica-tion would also be possible, as long as retailers and other buyers were held to account for the support they claim to provide. So while goodwill and stable supply can provide incentives, the big-gest incentives for retailers to ensure the claims they make around producer support are met will be the risk to their brands should they be called out for not complying to standards.

A developmental-chain model for aquaculture sustainability would inevitably create new kinds of depen-dencies between buyers and producers. And there is no guarantee that buyer-certification will improve conditions for developing world producers to 

Simon Bush Pangasius farm on the banks of the Mekong River near Can Tho, Vietnam. The farm shows the integrated nature of farms in the riverine landscape of the Mekong Delta.

Page 4: Reversing the Burden of Proof for Sustainable Aquaculture

30  |  Solutions  |  July-August 2016  |  www.thesolutionsjournal.org

Perspectives

be incorporated into global seafood value chains. But by giving recognition for ‘developmental’ modes of chain coordination, we can ensure that the responsibility for sustainable aquacul-ture is not placed on those with the least capacity for independent improve-ment. Instead of retailers undermining the capacity of farmers to respond to sustainability demands, responsibility will be placed at the feet of retailers (and other buyers) who do not replace the end consumer but do orchestrate global demand for fish products. If aquaculture can get this right, it will hold substantial lessons for any global food sector looking for successful models of fostering sustainability improvements. 

References1.  WorldFish. Financing smallholder aquaculture 

enterprises [online] (2011). http://pubs.iclarm.net/

resource_centre/WF_2798.pdf.

2.  Béné, C et al. Feeding 9 billion by 2050—putting fish 

back on the menu. Food Security 7, 261–274 (2015).

3.  FAO. The State of World Fisheries and Aquaculture 

(Rome, Food and Agriculture Organisation of the 

United Nations, 2014).

4.  Bush, SR et al. Certify sustainable aquaculture? 

Science 341, 9–10 (2013).

5.  Ha, TTT, Bush, SR, Mol, APJ & Van Dijk, H. Organic 

coasts? Regulatory challenges of certifying 

integrated shrimp–mangrove production systems 

in Vietnam. Journal of Rural Studies 28, 631–639 

(2012).

6.  Marschke, M & Wilkings, A. Is certification a viable 

option for small producer fish farmers in the global 

South? Insights from Vietnam. Marine Policy 50, 

197–206 (2015).

7.  Valderrma, D, Hishamunda, N & Zhou, X. 

Estimating employment in world aquaculture. FAO

Fisheries and Aquaculture Newsletter 45, 24–25 (2010).

8.  Ivarsson, I & Alvstam, CG. Supplier Upgrading in 

the home-furnishing value chain: an empirical 

study of IKEA’s sourcing in China and Southeast 

Asia. World Development 38, 1575–1587 (2010).

9.  Tlusty, MF. Environmental improvement of seafood 

through certification and ecolabelling: theory and 

analysis. Fish and Fisheries 13, 1–13 (2011).

10. Ca Mau Shrimp Aquaculture Improvement Project 

[online] (2016). https://www.sustainablefish.org/

aquaculture-improvement/ca-mau-shrimp-aip.

11. Sampson, BGS et al. Secure sustainable seafood from 

developing countries. Science 348, 504–506 (2015).

12. Ha, TTT, Bush, SR & Van Dijk, H. The cluster 

panacea?: Questioning the role of cooperative 

shrimp aquaculture in Vietnam. Aquaculture 388–

391, 89–98 (2013).

13. Soto, D, Aguilar-Manjarrez, J & Hishamunda, N. 

Building an Ecosystem Approach to Aquaculture (Food 

and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations, 

Rome, 2008).

Marjorie-Ann D. Sumaya / WorldFish Milkfish harvesting in Iloilo, Philippines.