Sabah Agri

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    1/19

    Debate on Farm Size andProductivity in the Context

    of Bangladesh

    Submitted By: Sazlin Sabah Samara Ahmad

    Id: 124092004Submitted To: Prof. Amir Hussain

    Dept. of f Economics

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    2/19

    United International University

    Abstract

    Agriculture accounts for only 21 per cent of the country's gross

    domestic product although the sector employs around 50 per cent

    of the national workforce. Every person working in the

    agriculture sector now owns only an average of 0.12 hectares of

    cropland. There is an already well established relationship

    between farm size and productivity which is that they r indirect

    proportionality or rather inverse relationship. But there are

    certain other issues and findings which bring out various other

    perspectives and how the relationship is changing with time and

    countrys state. Technology, labor availability, and fertility are

    among the main factors that effects the relation of productivity to

    farm size in countries like Bangladesh. Efficiency measures can

    help to demonstrate a different angle to this relationship if study

    is further spread to regional basis.The relationship need not be

    there for all size groups, for all regions, and for all crops so the

    indirectness of the relationship cant be generalized. .

    2

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    3/19

    1. Introduction

    Relationship between farm size and productivity in developing countries is one of theoldest issues in the academic arena for analyzing the agrarian structure. The debate on

    farm size and productivity relationship intensified, when Sen (1962, 1966) observed an

    inverse relationship between farm size and output per hectare in Indian agriculture,

    suggesting that small farms are more productive compared to large ones. This

    relationship is explained by the relative advantage of using more family labor by small

    farms that may reduce the monitoring and supervision costs of hired labor. These findings

    show that equity does matter for efficiency in the agricultural sector, and raise the

    question of redistributive land reform in most agrarian countries which includes countries

    such as Bangladesh. Since then, a lot of empirical studies have re-examined the problem

    from different angles using various statistical techniques in order to test Sens finding,

    and inverse relationship (IR) has been perceived as a stylized fact1 of rural

    development. In favor to the IR, Sen argues that the opportunity cost of a days labor by

    family members might be well below the daily wage rate of hired labor. Recent emphasis

    on positive relationship is explained by alluding to various imperfections in the capital

    market [Heltberg 1998, Swamy 1998, Dyer 1996-7]. Debate on the relationship between

    farm size and productivity is still a matter of concern especially at the policy level, as in

    agrarian economies like Bangladesh, redistributive land reform policies have not been

    successfully implemented and issues related to land rights of the poor are gathering

    momentum. New explanations for the nature of this relationship are constantly coming

    up while analyzing. One major emphasis in the recent literature is that the small farms are

    not as efficient as the large farms in agriculturally developed regions though this may not

    be the case in agriculturally backward regions. There is, however, a dichotomy in

    explaining the relationship between farm size and productivity (Toufique K. A., 1998).

    1Stylized facts are observations that have been made in so many contexts that they are widely understood to beempirical truths, to which theories must fit ( used especially in macroeconomic theory). Considered unhelpful ineconomic history where context is central.

    3

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    4/19

    1.1 Objective

    This paper is going to briefly address and review the relationship between the farm size

    and its productivity in the context of Bangladesh with reference to the existing studies

    based on this debate.

    2.0 Literature Review

    The inverse relationship between farm size and productivity in Bangladesh agriculture

    was established by the contribution of Hossain [1977] and Taslim [1989]. According to

    Hossain [1977] the cost of family labour is low for small farms and hence they use labour

    intensively. On the other hand Taslim [1989] brought the issue of high supervision costs

    of monitoring labour which explains why labour is less intensively used in large farms in

    comparison to the small ones. Toufique K A [1998] pointed out that both Taslim [1989]

    and Hossain [1977] did not analyze whether the inverse relationship reverses in

    agriculturally developed regions.

    Toufique [1998] points out some drawbacks of Hossain [1977]s study. First, was that

    the opportunity costs of family labour are low can be seriously questioned for many parts

    in Bangladesh especially where rapid and frequent out-migration has made the

    agricultural labor market tight. Second, was that most small farms also hires outside labor

    and this implies that the opportunity cost of family labor may not necessarily be low, so

    is the cost of supervising labor. Third, increasing involvement in off-farm activities

    because of the increase in microfinance will also mean a relatively high opportunity cost

    of family labor. So these indicate that family labor may not have a low opportunity cost.

    According to Toufique [1998] drawbacks of Taslim [1989]s study were: First, Taslim

    [1989] ignores the institutional infrastructure of rural labor markets as it relates more

    generally to transaction costs and more specifically to supervision costs. These

    institutional infrastructures will of course vary temporarily as well as spatially but they

    4

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    5/19

    have strong impact on decision-making process of the farmers/employers. Second,

    Taslim [1989] ignores that the small farms also face supervision costs as long as they hire

    outside labor.

    Abedin and Bose (1988) found out a positive relationship between farms size and

    productivity for modern rice production technology because the large farms used higher

    doses of purchased inputs such as fertilizers and pesticides. In Toufique [1998]s study,

    he mentions that the negative relationship is explained by recourse to the labour market

    and the positive relationship is explained by alluding to the differential access to the

    capital market in context of Bangladesh agriculture.

    Toufique, K. A. (1998) examined the relationship between farm size and productivity in

    Bangladesh agriculture by using simple linear regression model. He used hired labor and

    family labor as input variables and labor hours per decimal by sites and by crops as

    dependent variable. The major finding of Toufiques paper was that the large farms were

    more efficient in a high growth area such as Madhupur and small farms were more

    efficient in low growth area such as Chandina. Labor cost is low in high growth area then

    in low growth area. The larger the farm size the lower will be the capability to use family

    labor for supervising hired labor. Thus, the labor market institutions in Chandina were

    relatively inefficient as compared to the labor market institutions in Madhupur.

    Good, B. K. et al (2004) examined farming efficiency and the determinants of multiple

    job holdings by farms operators for the years 1996-2001. He used Lagrange under utility

    functions. He used hours worked, efficiency, house hold size, career choice, age, risk

    preference, farm experience, 2001 population per square mile, number of children,

    education, tenancy as input variables and farm efficiency as dependent variable. The

    major finding of this paper was that there was an inverse relationship between family

    efficiency and off farm labor supply. Farmers those were more efficient are less likely to

    work off the farm. This reflects a higher implicit farm wage for such operators.

    5

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    6/19

    One major emphasis in the recent literature is that the small farms are not as efficient as

    the large farms in agriculturally developed regions though this may not be the case in

    agriculturally backward regions. In the light of above-mentioned studies it is very clear

    that farm size and productivity are highly correlated but in different directions in some

    negative and in some positive. Farm sizes vary from country to country and also

    productivity.

    This paper is organized in the following sections: section1 introduction objective,

    Section 2: Literature Survey, Data analysis and methodology, Section 3: Land

    statistics of Bangladesh, Inverse Relationship Dogma, Productivity and Efficiency

    Measures, Section 4: Introduction of Technology, Section 5: Limitation and

    Recommendation and Conclusion followed by Reference.

    2.1 Data Collection & Analysis

    Data used and mentioned in this paper is collected from secondary sources mainly from

    the bureau of statistics, publications and journals available in the internet.

    2.2 Methodology

    This paper is mainly descriptive and analytical in nature briefly discussing the existing

    theoretical and empirical papers on the farm size and productivity debate and related

    issues.

    Usually the popular formulation used to test the relationship between farm size and ameasure of (average) productivity is based on the simple model

    Y= + ln A +

    6

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    7/19

    Y is the value (or quantity) of farm output per hectare, ln A is the natural logarithm of

    farm area planted and is the classical disturbance term. A negative value of in this

    specification represents an inverse relationship between farm size and productivity. Later

    studies included other regressors to control for the effects of household versus hired labor

    [Taslim(1989); Frisvold(1994), land quality [Carter (1984); Bhalla(1988); Bhalla &

    Roy(1988); Benjamin(1995)] & availability of credit [Berry & Cline(1979)]

    3.0 The Land Statistics of Bangladesh

    Geographical area of Bangladesh is about 56,000 square miles. (143,998 square

    kilometer) Out of which about 9 million hectares are cultivable land. But every year the

    cropland is shrinking for human settlement. It is estimated that the growing population

    pressure will use up 50 percent of the countrys cultivable land by 2025. Urbanization,

    industrialization and acquisition of land by the government for different purposes have

    been causing negative impact on the life and conditions of the peasants as well as socio-

    economic scenario of the country. Vast areas of land have also been devoured by the

    mighty rivers of Bangladesh. Moreover, land is fragmented every year in rural and urban

    areas due to growing population and the law of inheritance. A study conducted by UNDP

    & World Bank-WB calculated that due to fragmentation of 1.42 hectares into 10 holdings

    of 0.15 hectares each, the effectiveness of net cropped area are about 1.5 percent to a land

    owner. Moreover, per capita land that would support the basic needs of the population is

    fast decreasing. Bangladesh is one of the most densely populated countries of the world

    where 798 persons live in one square kilometer.

    Bangladesh agriculture has a very low and declining land-labor ratio. Over time, the

    average size of farms has become smaller and smaller. For example, in 1960 the average

    farm size was 1.4 hectares, but in 1984 it was less than one hectare. Along with

    decreasing farm size one can observe an increasingly unequal distribution of land

    7

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    8/19

    holdings and increasing landlessness. In the active tenancy market in Bangladesh, around

    25 percent of cultivable land is transferred, so that the distribution of cultivated land is

    less unequal than the distribution of ownership.

    Every person working in the agriculture sector now owns only an average of 0.12

    hectares of cropland. According to the classification of land, out of the total area, 63

    percent are being used for cultivation while 4.38 per cent for rural and urban housing and

    the rest includes forest & cultivable waste land. The amounts of one-crop, two-crop and

    three-crop lands are 3.5,3.7 and 0.99 hectares, respectively. Only rice is grown in 80 per

    cent of the total cultivable land, of which 50 per cent is dedicated to high yielding variety.

    But because of existing anomaly in land distribution, all khas lands not being recovered

    and handed over to the landless, and share croppers and small farmers having little or no

    share in production, the ultra poor and the deprived and the actual landless are suffering

    most.

    Official statistics also show that the country is losing more than one per cent or 80,000

    hectares each year from its original 13 million hectares of cropland due to urbanization,

    industrialization, unplanned rural housing and infrastructure building. Agriculture

    accounts for only 21 per cent of the country's gross domestic product although the sector

    employs around 50 per cent of the national workforce. Experts said if the trend is not

    reversed now, the country would permanently lose its food security, making its poor

    population more vulnerable to volatile international commodity prices.

    From the 2008 Agricultural Census of Bangladesh the current structure and nature of the

    agricultural sector can be understood. Agriculture Census is a robust and gigantic work as

    well as it is one of the largest nation-wide statistical operation.

    The following table shows that out of total 28.67 million households, the number of

    agriculture farm households (households operating 0.05 acres of cultivated area) has

    been recorded at 14.72 million which account for 51.33% of total households. Out of

    8

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    9/19

    total 51.33%, only 1.15% agriculture farm is in urban area while 50.18% is in rural

    areas.

    Fig .1 Distribution of Agriculture Farm Households by Urban, Rural and Division

    Source: Preliminary Report of the Agriculture Census 2008

    The highest percentage (65.12%) of agriculture farm has been recorded for

    Barisal Division followed by Khulna Division (59.09%) and Rajshahi Division

    (55.83%) respectively. The 2008 Agriculture Census also disclose the fact that

    out of total 3.31 million urban households, 0. 33 million households (9.97%) are

    tenant households while out of 25.35 million rural households, 14.38 million

    households (56.72%) are tenant households.

    3.1 Findings

    It has been found that a farm size between 7 and 12 acres is the most efficient (overall

    efficiency) in the contest of Bangladesh agriculture. This has an important policy

    implication in connection with the ceiling of land ownership in Bangladesh.

    9

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    10/19

    It is estimated that the agricultural land is declining by 1% per year and the land quality is

    deteriorating owing to degradation of soil fertility (e.g. nutrient imbalance), soil erosion

    and soil salinity. In addition, water resources are also shrinking. In order to produce more

    food for an increasing population, and raw materials for agro-industries, there is a need

    for increasing agricultural growth through higher productivity, including increased yield,

    agricultural intensification and diversification, and value addition.

    In order to achieve the GDP growth rate of 7% per year, agriculture must grow by at least

    4 to 4.5% per year (PRSP, 2005). This is presumably possible through an increase in

    agricultural productivity (for crops, horticulture, livestock, fisheries and forestry) based

    on modern agricultural technology and a supply chain linking farmers with consumers in

    the domestic as well as overseas markets.

    Small farms dominate the agrarian structure of Bangladesh. Therefore, performance of

    the sector greatly affects economic progress and peoples livelihood. To reduce rural

    poverty and improve rural livelihoods, it is necessary to recognize and to develop existing

    agricultural production system into a more dynamic and viable commercial sector.

    Agriculture has the potential to reduce food deficit as well as shortage of industrial raw

    materials, and also to generate employment opportunities with reasonable income, which

    will in turn help improve the standard of living of the rural people. The growth potential

    of most of the crops and other agricultural commodities are substantially higher than

    present level of production.

    3.2 The Inverse Relationship Dogma

    The inverse relationship was derived based on size class data; and Sen himself was

    however, aware of the limitation of his conclusion since he was using only aggregated

    data. Sen (1964) subsequently gave three alternative lines of explanation for this

    phenomenon, (i) technique-based, (ii) labor-based, and (iii) fertility-based.

    10

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    11/19

    In labor- based approach the inverse relationship is explained on two strong, if not

    unrealistic, assumptions: (a) the farmers large and small - are passive in responding to

    monitoring costs of hiring large doses of labor and (b) the labor market institutions are

    the same and static in all regions (backward and forward or stagnating and

    growing).

    Theoretically, inverse farm size and productivity relationship was based on three main

    factors. First, imperfection in the labor market, second, land credit and third, cropping

    intensity. Dual labor market2 hypothesis is the more common explanation for the

    imperfection in the labor market in relation to inverse farm size productivity relationship.

    (MPL > W) The rural labor market is divided between family labor and hired labor. Hired

    laborers will be more efficient (i.e. will provide more labor services per unit of time)

    when subject to more supervision. Family members a side from being better motivated

    then a laborer, perform a supervisory role with respect to hired labor. The marginal

    productivity of labor, in general, was found to be higher than the wage rate. The wage

    rate of family labor is found to be lower then the wage rate of hired labor. This duality is

    preserved by institutional restrictions (like the reluctance of women and children to join

    the labor market) and more importantly by the indivisibility of labor demand especially at

    harvesting and sowing when full time hired labor can be controlled better than part time

    hired labor since part time labor, has its own cultivation demands. Small farmers having

    cheaper inputs can be maximized through more use.

    According to Madhusudan Ghosh (1989) who looked at the changes in the agrarian

    structure of rural West Bengal during the seventies, hypothesized that in a dualistic

    agrarian structure in which large farms under-utilized land due to shortage of family

    labour and small farms under-utilized family labor due to scarcity of land, a reduction in

    the degree of inequality in the distribution of operational land would favorably affect

    agricultural productivity. He suggested that a reduction in inequality of land distribution

    through appropriate land reforms would result in higher agricultural productivity in West

    Bengal.

    2Dual labor market is defined as when economy is divided into two main sectors: Primary sector and Secondary sector

    11

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    12/19

    In his attempt to develop a theory of optimum land reform for dualistic agriculture, Raj

    Krishna, after examining various Indian studies based on Farm Management data, came

    to the conclusion that a reduction in the size of holdings and land concentration brought

    out by land reform, will not be associated with a reduction in output per acre, after a new

    equilibrium is established. On the contrary the output per hectare and hence the total

    output of a given area of land is likely to increase [Vijayakrishna (1995).]

    3.3 Productivity and Efficiency Measures

    Efficiency argument in favor of land reform is provided by the studies of IR in

    developing countries. However, the relevant comparison regarding the desirability of land

    reform is not whether smaller farms have higher average productivity (yield or value of

    output per hectare) but whether they show greater overall economic efficiency. Complete

    measures of efficiency like total factor productivity (TFP) or quasi-rent (Binswanger,

    Deininger and Feder; 1993) are used in recent studies for size comparison of farms.

    Economic efficiency and farm size relationship can be tested by efficiency measures

    based on distance function3 introduced by Shephard (1953).

    Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) helps to disaggregate economic efficiency for each

    farm into measures of scale and technical efficiency using only input and output quantity

    data. Hence determination of how relative share of each source of inefficiency alters

    across farms by size is possible. From DEA, measures of return to scale and technical

    efficiency can be developed using data on input and output quantities, whereas technical

    efficiency measured by TFP or profit function estimation relies on price data which is

    often unreliable. Production based approaches suffer from inconsistency of parameter

    estimates due to endogeneity of inputs and also needs restrictions for functional form.

    Distance functions rely on the construction of production frontiers that doesnt require

    3 A distance function is remarkably simple yet powerful concept. This function underpins nonparametric

    efficiency analysis & is also the basis for nonparametric approach for assessing productivity.

    12

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    13/19

    choice of functional form. Thus using efficiency measures can prove to be more useful as

    it serves as an unbiased estimator in such cases.

    4. Introduction of Technology

    Several economists put their views that the IR remains valid for traditional agriculture.

    As a result, small farms in most developing countries were perceived as more efficient

    than large farms before the 1980s. On the other hand, rapid technological changes and the

    expansion of commercial farming have changed the perception of efficiency toward small

    farms, suggesting that the IR diminished, when the agricultural sector moved towards

    modernization through the adoption of more capital intensive technology. Such

    transformation will pay more attention on other inputs such as fertilizer and modern

    variety of seeds rather than the importance of farm labor. Small farmers, in this regard,

    might be unable to compete, especially as the rapid sequence of new technological inputs

    requires investments that go beyond their capacity.

    The many technological changes and the expansion of commercial farming seem to have

    changed the picture. Using the same technology as employed on the large farms, the

    smallholder was more productive in the past because of his greater labour input. During

    the 70s, however, progressive and commercial farmers started to employ a higher level of

    technology. During the initial years, in particular, the new technology was not accessible

    to the small farmers, and the low level of information led to false investments resulting in

    financial losses which prevented future investments.

    An indication of this process is the sequence of rapid technological inputs within the

    process of the so-called green revolution. The new varieties required the purchasing of

    expensive seed at the beginning. Soon the existing irrigation facilities had to be improved

    by the addition of tubewells in order to ensure the availability of a timely and adequate

    supply of water. The low resistance to insects and pests necessitated the use of chemicals.

    Once seed and water were under control, the traditional bullock plough proved to be the

    next bottleneck in the attempt to increase productivity, and thousands of tractors with

    13

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    14/19

    machines were bought within a short time. This made it unnecessary to employ great

    numbers of tenants who owned bullocks, and very many were dismissed. This, once

    again, led to the substitution of herbicides for manual labour, and the introduction of

    mowing and threshing machines to carry out the harvest work.

    It is obvious that most of the smallholders could not cope with such a large volume of

    investment requirements within a short time. Quite a number had to give up farming

    following financial losses due to failure, or because they realized that they could not cope

    with the new requirements.

    This was at least in part due to the absence or imperfection of institutions for assisting

    smallholders to overcome their limitations. A more efficient cooperative system of credit,

    supply and marketing as well as of supporting production by group activities, the use of

    machinery etc., could have led to other results than those which we experienced during

    the 80s.

    The current agricultural technology system of Bangladesh, however, is unable to

    effectively generate, transfer and promote the use of modern technology to increase

    agricultural productivity and meet the changing needs of farmers. A dynamic agriculturaltechnology system is vital to ensure national food security and reduce poverty in the face

    of declining agricultural land base and increasing population. However, the continuing

    recent trend in agricultural research and extension will have a detrimental impact on the

    agricultural sector. Among the barriers to an effective national agricultural technology

    system are low levels of government spending on agricultural research and the inability

    of agricultural research institutes to generate relevant modern agricultural technology.

    One major constraint to higher agricultural productivity is the low level of government

    expenditure on agricultural research. At present, the expenditure is only about 0.2% of

    Agricultural GDP, compared to 0.6% for other developing countries and over 2% for

    developed countries. The following graph depicts this reducing trend:

    14

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    15/19

    Figure: 2

    Source: www.worldbank.org.bd

    Although aggregate spending on agricultural research and extension appears to have

    increased slightly, it is mostly due to an increase in spending on agricultural extension

    (ie, the transfer of technology to farmers).

    The wide range of recommendations in the study include areas for institutional reforms

    of the national agricultural research and extension system, ways to increase funding and

    exploring opportunities for growth of commercial high value agricultural products (such

    as fruits, vegetables, fish and poultry).

    5. Limitations & Recommendations

    15

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    16/19

    Mentionable limitations of this paper are the following:

    Due to time constraint detailed inclusion of many important papers were not

    possible.

    There was also a page limitation set by the instructor which restricted from

    diversifying the debate with respect to other related topics.

    This paper requires further elaboration on different existing models and broad

    study on current trend of the relationship between farm size and productivity.

    Study using primary data based on samples taken from the different regions of the

    country and its diverse farming characteristics would help establish the debate on

    inverse relationship more profusely.

    This paper doesnt include the current lending system for the Agricultural Sector

    and the rules set by the Bangladesh Bank. This could later prove to be a vital

    aspect regarding the credit access and availability for the rural subsistent small

    scale farmers and hence show how productivity is affected if further extension of

    this paper is held.

    Recommendations in the favor of developing small scale farming which will target more

    productivity are as follows:

    Agricultural Extension: This is the key driving force for the growth and

    development of agriculture in Bangladesh. To increase farm productivity and

    farmers income access to new technology is required. The role of extension is to

    deliver services and to speed up farmers access to and adoption of new

    technology. The Government is mandated to providing efficient and effective

    need based extension services to farmers to enable them to optimize their use of

    resource to augment self-sufficiency in food production and to improve their

    nutritional status. The Government can promote public, private and voluntary

    extension initiatives to achieve diverse agricultural goals and to address needs of

    target populations. Extension services should be provided to all categories of

    16

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    17/19

    farmers: landless, marginal, small, medium, large with special emphasis on

    women and youths. The Government should decentralize extension activities at

    the grass-roots level to deliver efficient and coordinated services.

    Agricultural Education and Training: Agricultural education system, especially

    at the diploma level will be strengthened and updated. Training should be

    administered on a regular basis to ensure effective extension-technology transfer

    and technology design and planning. Training for farmers and officials at all

    levels as basic mechanism should be implemented for enhancing occupational

    competence, professionalism and service morale.

    Agricultural Productivity: The Government can continue and strengthen its

    support for major crops related to food security and livelihood options. In addition

    measures should be taken to promote high value crops to enhance farmers

    income and boost agricultural export. Measures can be taken to increase cropping

    intensity, especially by bringing fallow land under cultivation. Diversification of

    agriculture can be pursued to promote food based nutrition security. The

    Government can monitor the supply and availability of inputs (seed, fertilizer,

    pesticides, irrigation, etc.) and credit distribution to farmers through DAE, BADC

    and other service providers. Efforts will be taken to provide micro-credit support

    at preferential rate for selective crops. Government and NGOs can together help to finance and extend a helping hand to

    the most grass root level farmers. If extension is possible through Union and

    Upazilla levels then it will be easier to access the small scale farmers.

    Non-farm Activities: The Government can promote poverty reduction through

    creation of employment opportunities in rural non-farm sectors. Necessary

    support will be provided for non-farm income generation activities for the poor

    and disadvantaged farmers.

    All these and many more other steps can be taken in collaborative approach to help

    the small scale farming more productive and hence efficient for a country like

    Bangladesh because as we can see land reforms and decentralization and rising

    population will only result in a decline in per head crop land in the coming years .

    17

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    18/19

    Conclusions

    To sum up, it is often pointed out that the difference in the size of farms is one of the

    reasons for the difference in yields. It is argued that small cultivators increase cropping

    intensity on their farms or have multiple crops and that family labour works intensively

    on such farms thereby increasing output per unit of land. However, studies carried out on

    the relation between size of farms and productivity show contradicting results. Studies

    based on aggregated data showed an inverse relationship, but studies based on

    disaggregated data failed to confirm this. The latter indicates that the inverse relationship

    exists in certain types of farms, but the relation cannot be generalized. In addition, the

    relationship need not be there for all size groups, for all regions, and for all crops. The

    debate thus remains inconclusive.

    Today it appears as if middle-sized farms turn out the highest productivity, while

    smallholders are increasingly unable to provide their cultivating family with a decent

    living. Due to shrinking farm size, they have to look for additional income, thus taking

    labour input away from the farms. The younger generation in particular is losing interest

    in cultivation, a process which is likely going to hit peaks unless steps are taken to revive

    the agricultural reforms with technological improvement and diversification.

    The vast majority of the worlds poorest households depend on farming for their

    livelihood. In the past, their earnings were often depressed by pro-urban and anti-

    agricultural biases of their own countrys policies. While progress has been made over

    the past two decades by numerous developing countries in reducing those policy biases,

    many trade-reducing price distortions remain inter-sectorally as well as within the

    agricultural sector of low-income countries.

    Higher agricultural productivity is an important component of the rural developmentstrategy for raising farm income; reducing poverty and making Bangladeshi agriculture

    more competitive in the global market.

    References

    18

  • 8/3/2019 Sabah Agri

    19/19

    Abedin, J. and G. K. Bose, 1988, Farm Size and Productivity Difference-a

    Decomposition Analysis, the Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol.16, No.3,

    September, pp. 71-79.

    Benjamin, Dwayne, (1995) 51-84 Can Unobserved Land Quality Explain the Inverse

    Productivity Relationship Journal of Development Economics 46

    Gilligan D. O, 1998, Farm Size, Productivity, and Economic Efficiency: Accounting for

    Differences in Efficiency of Farms by Size in Honduras American AgriculturalEconomics Association Annual Meetings.

    Hossain, M., 1977, Farm Size, Tenancy and Land Productivity: An Analysis of Farm

    Level Data in Bangladesh Agriculture, Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol. 3, No.5,pp.285-348.

    National Agricultural Policy, 2008; Draft 3 Ministry of Agriculture Government of the

    Peoples Republic of Bangladesh

    R. Mahesh, 2000, Farm Size- Productivity Relationship: Some Evidence from KeralaKIED Working Paper 2

    Rehnuma Amin Roadmap for improving agriculture productivity in Bangladesh

    www.worldbank.org.bd

    Sen A. K., 1962, An Aspect of Indian Agriculture, Economic Weekly, Vol.14, Nos. 4-6,

    pp.243-66.

    Taslim, M. A., 1989, Supervision Problems and the Size productivity Relation in

    Bangladesh Agriculture, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 51, No.1,pp.55-71.

    Toufique, K. A., 1998, The Relationship Between Farm Size and Productivity inBangladesh Agriculture: The Role Of Transaction Costs In Rural Labour Markets

    Preliminary Report Agriculture Census, 2008

    19