27
2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model Φ(L)y t = t , (75) where Φ(L)= I Φ 1 L Φ 2 L 2 −···− Φ p L p (76) is the (matric) lag polynomial. Provided that the stationary conditions hold we have analogously to the univariate case the vector MA representation of y t as y t 1 (L) t = t + i=1 Ψ i ti , (77) where Ψ i is an m × m coefficient matrix. 53

Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation

accounting

Consider the VAR(p) model

Φ(L)yt = εt,(75)

where

Φ(L) = I − Φ1L − Φ2L2 − · · · − ΦpLp(76)

is the (matric) lag polynomial.

Provided that the stationary conditions hold

we have analogously to the univariate case

the vector MA representation of yt as

yt = Φ−1(L)εt = εt +∞∑

i=1

Ψiεt−i,(77)

where Ψi is an m × m coefficient matrix.

53

Page 2: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

The error terms εt represent shocks in the

system.

Suppose we have a unit shock in εt then its

effect in y, s periods ahead is

∂yt+s

∂εt= Ψs.(78)

Accordingly the interpretation of the Ψ ma-

trices is that they represent marginal effects,

or the model’s response to a unit shock (or

innovation) at time point t in each of the

variables.

Economists call such parameters are as dy-

namic multipliers.

54

Page 3: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

For example, if we were told that the first

element in εt changes by δ1, that the sec-

ond element changes by δ2, . . . , and the mth

element changes by δm, then the combined

effect of these changes on the value of the

vector yt+s would be given by

Δyt+s =∂yt+s

∂ε1tδ1 + · · · + ∂yt+s

∂εmtδm = Ψsδ,

(79)

where δ′ = (δ1, . . . , δm).

55

Page 4: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

The response of yi to a unit shock in yj is

given the sequence, known as the impulse

multiplier function,

ψij,1, ψij,2, ψij,3, . . .,(80)

where ψij,k is the ijth element of the matrix

Ψk (i, j = 1, . . . , m).

Generally an impulse response function traces

the effect of a one-time shock to one of the

innovations on current and future values of

the endogenous variables.

56

Page 5: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

What about exogeneity (or Granger-causality)?

Suppose we have a bivariate VAR system

such that xt does not Granger cause y. Then

we can write⎛⎜⎝ yt

xt

⎞⎟⎠ =

⎛⎝ φ

(1)11 0

φ(1)21 φ

(1)22

⎞⎠ (

yt−1xt−1

)+ · · ·

+

⎛⎝ φ

(p)11 0

φ(p)21 φ

(p)22

⎞⎠ (

yt−pxt−p

)+

(ε1tε2t

).

(81)

Then under the stationarity condition

(I − Φ(L))−1 = I +∞∑

i=1

ΨiLi,(82)

where

Ψi =

⎛⎝ ψ

(i)11 0

ψ(i)21 ψ

(i)22

⎞⎠.(83)

Hence, we see that variable y does not react

to a shock of x.

57

Page 6: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Generally, if a variable, or a block of variables,

are strictly exogenous, then the implied zero

restrictions ensure that these variables do not

react to a shock to any of the endogenous

variables.

Nevertheless it is advised to be careful when

interpreting the possible (Granger) causali-

ties in the philosophical sense of causality

between variables.

Remark 2.6: See also the critique of impulse response

analysis in the end of this section.

58

Page 7: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Orthogonalized impulse response function

Noting that E(εtε′t) = Σε, we observe that

the components of εt are contemporaneously

correlated, meaning that they have overlap-

ping information to some extend.

59

Page 8: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Example 2.9. For example, in the equity-bond data

the contemporaneous VAR(2)-residual correlations are

=================================FTA DIV R20 TBILL

---------------------------------FTA 1DIV 0.123 1R20 -0.247 -0.013 1TBILL -0.133 0.081 0.456 1=================================

Many times, however, it is of interest to know

how ”new” information on yjt makes us re-

vise our forecasts on yt+s.

In order to single out the individual effects

the residuals must be first orthogonalized,

such that they become contemporaneously

uncorrelated (they are already serially uncor-

related).

Remark 2.7: If the error terms (εt) are already con-

temporaneously uncorrelated, naturally no orthogo-

nalization is needed.

60

Page 9: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Unfortunately orthogonalization, however, is

not unique in the sense that changing the

order of variables in y chances the results.

Nevertheless, there usually exist some guide-

lines (based on the economic theory) how the

ordering could be done in a specific situation.

Whatever the case, if we define a lower tri-

angular matrix S such that SS′ = Σε, and

νt = S−1εt,(84)

then I = S−1ΣεS′−1, implying

E(νtν′t) = S−1E(εtε′t)S′−1 = S−1ΣεS′−1 = I.

Consequently the new residuals are both un-

correlated over time as well as across equa-

tions. Furthermore, they have unit variances.

61

Page 10: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

The new vector MA representation becomes

yt =∞∑

i=0

Ψ∗i νt−i,(85)

where Ψ∗i = ΨiS (m × m matrices) so that

Ψ∗0 = S. The impulse response function of yi

to a unit shock in yj is then given by

ψ∗ij,0, ψ∗

ij,1, ψ∗ij,2, . . .(86)

62

Page 11: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Variance decomposition

The uncorrelatedness of νts allow the error

variance of the s step-ahead forecast of yit to

be decomposed into components accounted

for by these shocks, or innovations (this is

why this technique is usually called innova-

tion accounting).

Because the innovations have unit variances

(besides the uncorrelatedness), the compo-

nents of this error variance accounted for by

innovations to yj is given by

s∑k=0

ψ∗2ij,k.(87)

Comparing this to the sum of innovation re-

sponses we get a relative measure how im-

portant variable js innovations are in the ex-

plaining the variation in variable i at different

step-ahead forecasts, i.e.,

63

Page 12: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

R2ij,s = 100

∑sk=0 ψ∗2

ij,k∑mh=1

∑sk=0 ψ∗2

ih,k

.(88)

Thus, while impulse response functions trace

the effects of a shock to one endogenous

variable on to the other variables in the VAR,

variance decomposition separates the varia-

tion in an endogenous variable into the com-

ponent shocks to the VAR.

Letting s increase to infinity one gets the por-

tion of the total variance of yj that is due to

the disturbance term εj of yj.

64

Page 13: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

On the ordering of variables

As was mentioned earlier, when there is con-

temporaneous correlation between the resid-

uals, i.e., cov(εt) = Σε �= I the orthogo-

nalized impulse response coefficients are not

unique. There are no statistical methods to

define the ordering. It must be done by the

analyst!

65

Page 14: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

It is recommended that various orderings should

be tried to see whether the resulting interpre-

tations are consistent.

The principle is that the first variable should

be selected such that it is the only one with

potential immediate impact on all other vari-

ables.

The second variable may have an immediate

impact on the last m − 2 components of yt,

but not on y1t, the first component, and so

on. Of course this is usually a difficult task

in practice.

66

Page 15: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Selection of the S matrix

Selection of the S matrix, where SS′ = Σε,

actually defines also the ordering of variables.

Selecting it as a lower triangular matrix im-

plies that the first variable is the one affecting

(potentially) the all others, the second to the

m − 2 rest (besides itself) and so on.

67

Page 16: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

One generally used method in choosing S

is to use Cholesky decomposition which re-

sults to a lower triangular matrix with posi-

tive main diagonal elements.∗

∗For example, if the covariance matrix is

Σ =

(σ2

1 σ12

σ21 σ22

)then if Σ = SS′, where

S =

(s11 0s21 s22

)We get

Σ =

(σ2

1 σ12

σ21 σ22

)=

(s11 0s21 s22

) (s11 s21

0 s22

)

=

(s211 s11s21

s21s11 s221 + s2

22

).

Thus s211 = σ2

1, s21s11 = σ21 = σ12, ands221 + s2

22 = σ22. Solving these yields s11 = σ1,

s21 = σ21/σ1, and s22 =√

σ22 − σ2

21/σ21. That is,

S =

(σ1 0

σ21/σ1 (σ22 − σ2

21/σ21)

1

2

).

68

Page 17: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Example 2.10: Let us choose in our example two or-derings. One with stock market series first followedby bond market series

[(I: FTA, DIV, R20, TBILL)],

and an ordering with interest rate variables first fol-lowed by stock markets series

[(II: TBILL, R20, DIV, FTA)].

In EViews the order is simply defined in the Cholesky

ordering option. Below are results in graphs with I:

FTA, DIV, R20, TBILL; II: R20, TBILL DIV, FTA,

and III: General impulse response function.

69

Page 18: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Impulse responses:

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DTBILL

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DFTA

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DDIV

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DR20

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DTBILL

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DTBILL

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DTBILL

Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

Order {FTA, DIV, R20, TBILL}

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DTBILL

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DFTA

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DDIV

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DR20

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DTBILL

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DTBILL

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DTBILL

Response to Cholesky One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

Order {TBILL, R20, DIV, FTA}

70

Page 19: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Impulse responses continue:

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DFTA

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DDIV

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DR20

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DFTA to DTBILL

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DFTA

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DDIV

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DR20

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DDIV to DTBILL

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DR20 to DTBILL

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DFTA

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DDIV

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DR20

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Response of DTBILL to DTBILL

Response to Generalized One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

71

Page 20: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

General Impulse Response Function

The general impulse response function aredefined as‡‡

GI(j, δi,Ft−1) = E[yt+j|εit = δi,Ft−1] − E[yt+j|Ft−1].

(89)

That is difference of conditional expectation

given an one time shock occurs in series j.

These coincide with the orthogonalized im-

pulse responses if the residual covariance ma-

trix Σ is diagonal.

‡‡Pesaran, M. Hashem and Yongcheol Shin (1998).Impulse Response Analysis in Linear MultivariateModels, Economics Letters, 58, 17-29.

72

Page 21: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Variance decomposition graphs of the equity-bond data

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DFTA variance due to DFTA

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DFTA variance due to DDIV

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DFTA variance due to DR20

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DFTA variance due to DTBILL

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DDIV variance due to DFTA

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DDIV variance due to DDIV

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DDIV variance due to DR20

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DDIV variance due to DTBILL

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DR20 variance due to DFTA

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DR20 variance due to DDIV

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DR20 variance due to DR20

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DR20 variance due to DTBILL

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DTBILL variance due to DFTA

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DTBILL variance due to DDIV

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DTBILL variance due to DR20

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent DTBILL variance due to DTBILL

Variance Decomposition ± 2 S.E.

73

Page 22: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Accumulated Responses

Accumulated responses for s periods ahead

of a unit shock in variable i on variable j

may be determined by summing up the cor-

responding response coefficients. That is,

ψ(s)ij =

s∑k=0

ψij,k.(90)

The total accumulated effect is obtained by

ψ(∞)ij =

∞∑k=0

ψij,k.(91)

In economics this is called the total multi-

plier.

Particularly these may be of interest if the

variables are first differences, like the stock

returns.

For the stock returns the impulse responses

indicate the return effects while the accumu-

lated responses indicate the price effects.

74

Page 23: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

All accumulated responses are obtained by

summing the MA-matrices

Ψ(s) =∞∑

k=0

Ψk,(92)

with Ψ(∞) = Ψ(1), where

Ψ(L) = 1 + Ψ1L + Ψ2L2 + · · ·.(93)

is the lag polynomial of the MA-representation

yt = Ψ(L)εt.(94)

75

Page 24: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

On estimation of the impulse

response coefficients

Consider the VAR(p) model

yt = Φ1yt−1 + · · · + Φpyt−p + εt(95)

or

Φ(L)yt = εt.(96)

76

Page 25: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Then under stationarity the vector MA rep-

resentation is

yt = εt + Ψ1εt−1 + Ψ2εt−2 + · · ·(97)

When we have estimates of the AR-matrices

Φi denoted by Φ̂i, i = 1, . . . , p the next prob-

lem is to construct estimates for MA matrices

Ψj. It can be shown that

Ψj =j∑

i=1

Ψj−iΦi(98)

with Ψ0 = I, and Φj = 0 when i > p. Conse-

quently, the estimates can be obtained by re-

placing Φi’s by the corresponding estimates.

77

Page 26: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Next we have to obtain the orthogonalized

impulse response coefficients. This can be

done easily, for letting S be the Cholesky de-

composition of Σε such that

Σε = SS′,(99)

we can write

yt =∑∞

i=0 Ψiεt−i

=∑∞

i=0 ΨiSS−1εt−i

=∑∞

i=0 Ψ∗i νt−i,

(100)

where

Ψ∗i = ΨiS(101)

and νt = S−1εt. Then

Cov(νt) = S−1ΣεS′−1

= I.(102)

The estimates for Ψ∗i are obtained by replac-

ing Ψt with its estimates and using Cholesky

decomposition of Σ̂ε.

78

Page 27: Variance decomposition and innovation accountinglipas.uwasa.fi/~sjp/Teaching/Afts/Lectures/etsc25.pdf · 2.5 Variance decomposition and innovation accounting Consider the VAR(p) model(75)

Critique of Impulse Response Analysis

Ordering of variables is one problem.

Interpretations related to Granger-causality

from the ordered impulse response analysis

may not be valid.

If important variables are omitted from the

system, their effects go to the residuals and

hence may lead to major distortions in the

impulse responses and the structural inter-

pretations of the results.

79