Yoon 1019

  • Upload
    3rlang

  • View
    213

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    1/42

    Investment in Childrens Human Capital:Implications of PROGRESA

    Yoonyoung Cho

    November 2004

    University of Wisconsin, Madison

    Abstract: This paper investigates the effects of an educational subsidy program in Mexico,

    PROGRESA, on investment in childrens human capital. I develop a dynamic behavioral model

    to pursue three objectives. First, I quantify the effect of the subsidy on schooling and human

    capital accumulation. Second, I investigate how the effects vary by household and individual

    characteristics. Third, I draw policy implications using the model and empirical estimates

    from it. My model shows that when parents use childrens earnings as a general source of

    household income, either under a borrowing constraint or impure altruism, parents under-invest

    in childrens education. An educational subsidy program such as PROGRESA can mitigate

    this inefficiency and increase educational attainment. The model suggests that the positive

    effects of the subsidy are greater for children from larger families and for older female children.

    These model predictions are confirmed in the empirical estimates. Moreover, I use the model

    and underlying parameters to conduct policy experiments and find that an educational subsidy

    program that applies differential subsidy rates by ability and family size can be more effective

    in reallocating resources to encourage human capital accumulation.

    JEL Classification: J24, I21, H52.

    Keywords: Human capital accumulation, schooling, subsidy.

    This paper owes an enormous debt of gratitude to John Karl Scholz and Ananth Seshadri for constant support

    and encouragement. Robert Haveman and Barbara Wolfe made valuable comments. I would like to thank all

    seminar participants at the University of Wisconsin, Northern Illinois University and the University of Buffalo.Department of Economics, 1180 Observatory Dr., Madison, WI 53706, email:[email protected]

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    2/42

    I. Introduction

    Increasing formal education is considered by many to be a way to reduce child labor, alleviate

    poverty, and, in the long run, contribute to the growth of the whole economy. For these reasons,

    education has received a great deal of attention. Despite this attention, however, individual

    households may not be able to invest enough in childrens human capital. Especially in de-

    veloping countries, child labor and poverty is considered to be a main deterrent of education.

    Consequently, policy makers in these countries have implemented interventions to encourage

    human capital accumulation.

    The educational subsidy program PROGRESA1 in Mexico has been recognized as a policy

    that successfully encourages school attendance among low income households children in the

    countrys rural areas. Much research has been devoted to evaluating the effects of the program

    on numerous aspects of household behaviors, including schooling decisions. These studies show

    there is a significant increase in schooling due to the program.

    For example, Schultz (2000, 2001) finds that there is a significant effect of PROGRESA on

    increasing school enrollment. The analysis is based on a comparison of households before and

    after program participation and the localities where the program does and does not take effect.

    Although this difference-in-difference analysis clearly shows the effects, it is limited in that it

    does not provide the answer to how effective the program is, nor can the estimates be usefuldirectly to explain what would happen when the policy is changed.

    To investigate PROGRESAs effectiveness, I address the more fundamental questions of what

    determines childrens schooling in the household, what are the factors that induce the govern-

    ments intervention into the educational decision, and how can a subsidy program improve them?

    In an attempt to answer these questions, I develop a dynamic model in which childrens human

    capital accumulation is determined from the parents perspectives.

    The human capital production and the optimal decision process follows Ben-Porath (1967),

    which endogenizes the schooling decision considering the human capital production function.

    Moreover, I incorporate parents as a decision maker so as to capture the households effect on

    the decision of childrens human capital. In my model, parents are assumed to be altruistic

    in the sense that they care about childrens income, which consists of childrens earnings and

    parents transfers to children. As a result, the final stock of human capital affects the decision

    makers utility. Capital market imperfection and a subsidy program are added to characterize

    poor households and the policy environment in rural areas of Mexico.

    1A Spanish acronym for Programa Nacional de Educacion, Salud y Alimentacion, which means national pro-

    gram for education, health and nutrition.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    3/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 2

    Parents determine a childs time investment in human capital accumulation until the child be-

    comes independent and leaves its natal household. A childs time is allocated between humancapital accumulation and earnings-generating activity. Since childrens labor earnings are con-

    tributed to the households budget, parental investment in a childs human capital depends on

    how productive the child is, how much the parents rely on the childs earnings, and how al-

    truistic the parents are towards the child. A childs productivity depends on his or her ability.

    The extent to which parents rely on the childs earnings depends on the flexibility of the capital

    market and parents lifetime income flow.

    By the time the child is independent and no longer pools its earnings into the parents budget,

    the human capital that the child has accumulated will determine his or her lifetime earnings.

    Since parents are altruistic and care about the childs income, parents will make a cash transfer

    to the child if they can and if it is needed. Thus, in every period, when determining a childs

    time allocation, parents mainly consider two factors about the childs human capital: one is the

    amount of labor earnings that the child contributes to the household budget, and the other is

    the parents altruism, which considers the childs future earnings.

    My model considers factors that generate under-investment in human capital compared to the

    social optimum. One of these are capital market imperfections that restrict parents from borrow-

    ing against their future income. For this reason, parents put more value on current consumption,

    and thereby use childrens earnings, which reduces investment in their childrens human capital.Another source is the fact that parents are making schooling decisions on behalf of their children.

    Since parents are not able to extract a grown childs earnings, they do not fully consider the

    lifetime earnings of the child. In addition, impure altruism reduces the extent to which parents

    care about childrens future income.

    There are several previous analyses that examine PROGRESA. Among them, Attanasio, Meghir

    and Santiago (2001) and Todd and Wolpin (2003) endogenize the schooling decision and analyze

    the subsidy effects of PROGRESA on schooling.

    In Attanasio, Meghir and Santiago (2001), the decision maker chooses schooling so as to maxi-

    mize the childs lifetime earnings, which are assumed to be a quadratic function of the years of

    schooling of an individual. Since the decision maker is already assumed to be maximizing life-

    time earnings, the model does not provide any reason why the government intervenes to change

    the outcome of the decision. However, schooling level of governments intervention and analysis

    is mainly primary or secondary school, where parents are more likely to make decisions on their

    behalf. If parents educational investment decisions differs from maximizing each childs lifetime

    earnings, estimates of the schooling decisions that ignore the contradictions discussed here will

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    4/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 3

    be biased. As mentioned above, in my model, parents are likely to under-invest in childrens

    human capital.

    In another study, Todd and Wolpin (2003) addresses parents decisions concerning fertility and

    childrens schooling. They model parents utility as a function of diverse arguments including

    childrens activities of either working, schooling, or staying home. The parameters of each

    argument, which reflect parents preferences for it, are allowed to vary with childrens gender

    and age according to the household characteristics. Grown children are assumed to have no

    interaction with parents in the sense that they do not pool their income into household budget

    and parents utility does not include any characteristics of their grown children. Therefore,

    the positive incentive for parents to invest in childrens human capital here is solely dependent

    on parents preference for schooling. However, Todd and Wolpins model is not explicit in the

    reasons why parents might derive different utility from the schooling of children with different

    characteristics, even after controlling for the differences in labor earnings.

    My model takes a different approach by specifying human capital accumulation. Households face

    borrowing constraints and the more these constraints bind, or the less altruistic the parents are,

    the lower the parents investment in childrens human capital. When the subsidy is introduced, it

    mitigates parents under-investment by increasing childrens time investment in human capital.

    The effects of subsidy are expected to vary by household and individual characteristics, and

    so does the educational decision. Specifically, I focus on the educational decision and subsidyeffects on children from different sizes of families and of different genders.

    My model and its empirical test finds that larger households are more borrowing constrained and

    therefore produce less education for their children. Subsidies, however, have greater effects on

    households with more children than for households with fewer children. I also test and reject the

    hypothesis that the gender difference in education might be due to parents unequal altruism.

    The effects of the subsidy are the same across genders for primary school education, and are

    greater for female than male children for secondary school.

    The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, I describe the data used, including the

    details of the program design and some descriptive statistics. Section 3 presents a dynamic

    model through which parents decide educational investments in children. Section 4 calibrates

    the model, presents the outcomes and discusses policy implications. Section 5 empirically tests

    the validity of the model by analyzing the effects of PROGRESA on schooling. In section 6,

    based on the model, I conduct policy experiments to examine ways that policy goals can be

    more effectively achieved. Section 7 concludes.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    5/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 4

    II. Data and Descriptive Analysis

    IIa. Program Design and Data

    PROGRESA began in 1998. It targets poor households in rural areas and provides subsidies

    for selected households conditional on childrens school attendance and regular visits to a health

    care clinic. The purpose of the program is to create incentives for poor households to invest in

    the human capital of their children.

    For this purpose, PROGRESA includes two components: a health and nutritional program and

    an educational subsidy program. The health and nutritional component of the program provides

    mothers and infants with regular health care, and conditional on the observance of the required

    health check-ups, it also provides nutritional supplements. The educational component of the

    program includes subsidies for parents who send their children to school.

    A recent appraisal of PROGRESA shows that the program is growing. By the year 2000,

    almost 40% of all rural families are covered by this program, which amounts to 20% of the

    federal budget allotted to social programs and to 0.2% of the GDP. The Mexican government is

    currently considering extending the program to urban areas.2

    There are two notable aspects of PROGRESAs design. One is that the subsidies are contingenton school attendance. The other is the social-experimental aspect of random assignment that

    determines which localities will take part in the program. PROGRESA is introduced sequentially

    to program localities first and to others later. The selection of program localities and eligible

    households, and the corresponding data collection process is as follows.

    Localities, where a high proportion of households are living in extreme poverty in seven Mexican

    states, are selected. According to the sequential expansion of the program, among the chosen

    6,396 localities, 4,546 of them are covered by the first phase of the program and the other 1,850

    localities are covered by the later phases. Based on a households economic situation, poor

    households are designated to be eligible for this program.3

    2The Mexican government changed the name of PROGRESA to Oportunidades but retained the programs

    main elements.3The beneficiary households are selected by the following three steps. First, the poverty condition comparing

    the families monthly income per capita and the cost of a basic food basket is estimated. In addition to the

    approximate poverty condition, the classification is conducted according to the households characteristics, which

    classifies the households either in extreme poverty or not in extreme poverty. Finally, taking account of regional

    differences and incorporating the poverty conditions, the eligible households are selected. For detailed process

    about defining poverty and selecting eligible households, see Skoufias, Davis and Behrman (1999).

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    6/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 5

    According to the structure of the program, corresponding samples are randomly selected from

    each locality. These consist of 320 treatment localities, which represent the program localitieswhere the program is introduced in the first phase, and 186 control localities, which serve as a

    control group in which the program is not introduced during the period of this analysis. Each

    survey covers both eligible and non-eligible households.

    The data I use include the 1997 census, the March 1998 baseline survey before the program

    onset, and three evaluation surveys conducted in November 1998, June 1999, and November

    1999, after the program was introduced. Each data set contains individual information such

    as demographic characteristics and school attendance, household information including family

    composition and income, and locality information, such as the presence of schools.

    These data sets, tracking the same households and individuals in eligible and non-eligible house-

    holds in both the treatment and the control localities, form a short period panel and serve as a

    main data for analysis. Since there is attrition in the data,4 only those individuals covered by

    at least two data sets are used for the analysis.

    IIb. Descriptive Analysis

    PROGRESA

    Once the household in the program locality is designated an eligible household,

    5

    they can par-ticipate in the health and nutritional and/or the educational component according to the ages

    of the children. The health and nutritional component usually provides health service to women

    and infants, while the educational component subsidizes households with children aged from

    eight to sixteen. For the purpose of this analysis, however, only the educational component of

    the program is considered.

    The conditional subsidy for schooling provides an exogenous shift of the costs of education,

    where subsidy rates differ across the gender and the ages of children. Table 1 summarizes the

    amount of scholarship that the participating households receive.6 At the ages of six or seven,

    children usually enter primary school. To provide a greater incentive to the parents of older

    and female children, the amount of subsidy increases with age and is slightly higher for female

    children. The subsidy amount for secondary school is much higher, in order to encourage more

    children to progress from primary to secondary school.

    4In particular, the second baseline survey only covers children ages six through sixteen in the schooling segment

    of the data, and the number of observations is far less than the other data sets. The other data sets usually have

    information about all members in the household.5About 78 percent of the sample is identified as eligible for PROGRESA.6The subsidy varies by grade, but is not contingent on age.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    7/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 6

    Table 1: Payments in Pesos per Month for School Attendance under PROGRESA.

    Educational Level Corresponding Age Male Child Female Child

    Primary

    3rd grade 8-9 71 71

    4th grade 9-10 81 81

    5th grade 10-11 107 107

    6th grade 11-12 138 138

    Secondary

    1st grade 12-13 204 214

    2nd grade 13-14 214 240

    3rd grade 15-16 230 260

    Source: Schultz (2000, Table 1) All values in 1998 pesos.

    Child Labor

    The opportunity cost of sending children to school is the foregone labor earnings from work. 7

    Table 2 shows the average earnings of children in the labor market by gender and age. Although

    not a great number of children under fourteen work and the earnings data is noisy, earnings

    from child labor are not trivial, considering that the average monthly earnings of working adults

    over 17 years old are approximately 800 pesos.

    Child labor, despite its illegality, is the main reason why children do not attend school.8 Children

    aged from thirteen to sixteen, who are usually enrolled in secondary school, show a higher

    tendency to participate in the labor market and have substantial earnings that increase steadily

    with age.

    Due to the increasing opportunity cost, the school enrollment rate for children decreases quickly

    as children age. Table 3 shows the school enrollment rates for each age and gender in the 1997

    census, before PROGRESA began. Since a number of children drop out of school to work in

    the labor market or to participate in home production, the enrollment rate for older children isvery low.

    7The Federal Labor Law in Mexico establishes age fourteen as the basic minimum age for work. Those children

    under age eighteen are required to have permission from a legal guardian or parent in order to work. In addition

    to that, primary and secondary education in Mexico is mandatory. However, government enforcement is far from

    strict and is only applied in the formal sector, while a great number of children are working for a family business

    or in the informal sector.8The earnings in this table are only the observed ones of those who work in the labor market and reported to

    the survey. If working in the informal and non-paid market, or participating in home production are counted, the

    opportunity cost of schooling would be larger.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    8/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 7

    Table 2: Child Labor and Average Monthly Earnings of Working Children.

    Male Female

    AgeN of

    Observations

    N of

    Working

    Monthly

    Earnings

    N of

    Observations

    N of

    Working

    Monthly

    Earnings

    8

    9

    10

    11

    12

    13

    14

    15

    16

    1,478

    1,720

    1,933

    1,760

    1,723

    1,754

    1,760

    1,745

    1,601

    23

    24

    25

    44

    93

    167

    283

    585

    643

    460

    358

    517

    359

    528

    516

    596

    675

    707

    1,762

    1,700

    1,813

    1,798

    1,727

    1,697

    1,626

    1,623

    1,442

    5

    9

    13

    16

    35

    58

    82

    193

    201

    195

    269

    210

    479

    405

    477

    535

    619

    651

    Source: PROGRESA, 1997 Census data. Earnings are in 1998 pesos.

    The reduction in enrollment rate for older female children is even greater than it is for older

    male children. Consequently the average years of schooling of adults between age seventeen

    and forty in the data are 5.1 and 4.6 years for men and women, respectively. If adults older

    than forty are included, the average years of schooling of men and women are 3.8 and 3.2 years

    respectively. The average years of schooling increases and the gap between men and women

    decreases in younger generations.

    Table 3: School Enrollment Rates (%).

    Age 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

    Male 88.2 92.2 94.3 94.5 93.3 92.5 84.9 75.1 60.1 43.5 33.5

    (3.2) (2.6) (2.3) (2.2) (2.4) (2.6) (3.5) (4.3) (4.8) (4.7) (4.7)

    Female 87.2 92.2 94.1 94.9 93.6 91.7 78.0 65.3 50.0 35.3 24.7

    (3.3) (2.6) (2.3) (2.0) (2.4) (2.7) (4.0) (4.7) (5.0) (4.3) (4.3)Source: PROGRESA, 1997 Census. The standard deviations are in parentheses. Number of observations: male=19,778 and female=18,835.

    Returns to Schooling

    The main incentive for parents to invest in childrens education is that childrens earnings in-

    crease.9 Therefore, parents have an incentive to invest in childrens human capital as long as

    9Many papers are devoted to estimate the increase in earnings due to the increase in education, as returns to

    schooling: e.g. Mincer (1974), Wills (1986), and Card (1999).

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    9/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 8

    childrens earnings augment households budget. In addition, if the parents are forward looking

    and altruistic, in the sense that they care about their childrens income in the future, they willalso invest in childrens schooling.

    Consider Table 4 which summarizes the distribution of educational attainment and the mean age,

    labor force participation and monthly earnings for each educational level by gender. Educational

    attainment is categorized as no education, less than primary, less than secondary, secondary, ter-

    tiary, and post tertiary education.10 As suggested in the table, education is positively correlated

    with earnings.

    Nevertheless, the majority of people living in rural areas of Mexico have less than primary

    education. Although younger generations seem to obtain morer education, their educationalattainment is still low, and only about ten percent go beyond the secondary level.

    Table 4: Age, Labor Force Participation (LFP) and Earnings by Educational Attainment.

    Men Women

    Last Grade Achieved % Age LFP Earnings % Age LFP Earnings

    No Education 23.5 52 76.9 650 33.9 51 11.8 502

    Less than Primary 40.4 42 86.2 772 34.9 39 13.2 620

    Less than Secondary 24.0 28 84.3 881 21.8 26 18.0 803

    Secondary 9.9 24 76.2 970 7.8 23 21.9 895Tertiary 1.7 27 69.4 1,398 1.3 25 35.0 1,725

    Post Tertiary 0.6 33 81.6 2,319 0.4 30 54.5 2,170

    Total 100.0 39 82.2 808 100.0 39 13.9 661

    Source: PROGRESA, 1997 Census. Number of observations: men=33,198 and women=33,279

    Other Factors

    There are number of other factors that might affect parents decisions on childrens education.

    For example, old age support may be a reason that parents invest more in sons than daughters,10Primary education, which corresponds to the Primaria in Mexico, is equivalent to elementary school in the

    U.S. Children often attend Preescolar (Preschool) or Kinder (Kindergarten) b efore going to Primaria. Thus, Less

    than Primary Education includes those who have attended Preschool, Kindergarten, or elementary school and fail

    to finish elementary school. Secondary education, corresponding to Secundaria in Mexico, is a three year course

    similar to junior high school. Less than Secondary includes secondary school dropouts, and Secondary includes

    those who graduated from secondary school. There are two different kinds of tertiary institutes. Normal Basica

    is a job-preparation technical institute, while Preparatoria is equivalent to U.S. high school education. Tertiary

    includes those who graduated from either one of these institutes. The post tertiary education includes those who

    finish Profesional which is college level, and Posgrado which is equivalent to a masters degree and above.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    10/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 9

    or the first born child than the others. However, the remittances patterns that grown children

    provide for their parents are not available from the PROGRESA data set.

    To get some idea of this pattern, I examine an auxiliary data set, the Mexican Health and Aging

    Study (MHAS).11 According to these data, in less urban areas of Mexico, the proportion of

    grown children making reverse transfers to their aged parents is around 5 .1% overall, when the

    households of children are poor. Although the definition of poor households in the data set is

    not rigorously defined and rather depends on parents subjective perceptions, financial support

    from children does not seem to be of great importance.

    Some studies use parental preferences to explain the educational outcomes of each child and

    the differences of these outcomes across children. Todd and Wolpin (2003), for example, findsthat parents derive different utility across children even when the children engage in the same

    activity. Behrman, Pollak, and Taubman (1986) finds that parents have equal concern for sons

    and daughters, or when returns to education in the marriage market are incorporated slightly

    prefer daughters.

    However, in this analysis, I focus on human capital as a main channel that affects parents

    decisions rather than considering differential parental preferences towards each child.

    III. Analytical Framework

    I develop a dynamic model to investigate how parents invest in childrens education. In this

    section, the description of the basic model, its solution and implications follow.

    IIIa. Model

    Suppose the life of the economic agent consists of three phases: childhood, young adulthood,

    and old age. The decision process of each phase is summarized as follows.

    Childhood: No direct decision is made by the agent. During this period children are under

    the parents control, depend on their parents for their schooling decisions, and pool theirincome to augment the household budget.

    Young Adulthood (young parent): From period t = 0 to period t = T 1 the economic

    agent makes decisions about consumption (savings) and their childrens human capital

    accumulation. The households budget is the sum of the parents and childrens income,

    if the children work.11The MHAS is conducted by the National Institute for Statistics, Geography and Information Technology, in

    alliance with universities in the U.S., including the University of Pennsylvania. They survey individuals over age

    55 and focus mainly on their health.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    11/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 10

    Old Age (old parent): From period t = T, when the child now becomes young adult himself

    or herself, to periodt

    =D

    , the end of an agents life, the agent decides on its optimalconsumption path given accumulated assets from previous periods. During this period,

    the independent childrens decision does not affect parents budgets nor utility. Altruistic

    old parents, however, derive positive utility from their childrens general wellbeing, which

    will depend on childrens income level determined from the previous periods.

    Formally, an economic agents decision problem throughout life is maximizing the sum of the

    present stream of discounted utility of each period, from young adulthood to old age. Let

    B(AT, HT, F) be the value obtained from time T onwards, which depends on accumulated

    assets AT, childrens human capital HT by the time t = T, and the amount of transfer fromparents to children F.12 Note that the agent begins young adulthood, with his or her human

    capital and initial assets already decided by his or her parents.

    The lifetime decision problem that the parents face through young adulthood to their old age,

    defined as W(E+ A0) is,

    W(E+ A0) = maxT1t=0

    tu(Ct) + TB(AT, HT, F) (1)

    s.t. Ct +Nk=1

    Ckt + At+1 Et +Nk=1

    Ekt + (1 + r)At, t = 0,...,T 2,

    Ct +Nk=1

    Ckt +Nk=1

    Fk + At+1 Et +Nk=1

    Ekt + (1 + r)At, t = T 1

    where W(E+ A0) is some function of parents wealth, a sum of earnings (E) and initial assets

    (A0), is a discount rate, N is the number of children, and r is risk-free interest rate. The

    utility function has the usual properties including u() > 0 and u() < 0. Parents earnings are

    determined by their human capital which are already determined from the previous generation:

    Et is exogenous. The budget constraint shows that current parents consumption plus childrens

    consumption, Ct +Nk=1

    Ckt, and savings for the next period, At+1, cannot exceed the sum of

    parents income, Et, aggregate childrens income,Nk=1

    Ekt, and savings from the previous period,

    (1 + r)At. At t = T 1, parents also make decisions about how much transfer they will make

    to each child (Fk).

    12Ht and F denote the aggregate human capital stock and transfer of each child at time t so that Ht =

    {H1t,...,HNt}, and F = {F1,...,FN} , where N is the total number of children in this household.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    12/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 11

    Each childs earnings consists of potential labor market earnings and subsidies for education

    provided by the government. The childs labor earnings depend on the stock of human capitalaccumulated thus far and the market time of labor, while the government provides subsidies for

    non-market time used for education to compensate for the loss of labor earnings due to human

    capital accumulation. Subsidies are set at some proportion of potential wage earnings. Thus

    the childs earnings which are composed of potential wage earnings and governments subsidies

    are specified as

    Ekt = (1 Ikt)RtHkt + IktRtHkt

    where Ikt is the proportion of time spent accumulating human capital, Rt is the rental rate for

    human capital, Hkt is the current stock of human capital and (0, 1) is a subsidy rate.

    A child is costly but not as costly as an adult, so childrens consumption is scaled so thatNk=1

    Ckt = (N)Ct where (N) is an equivalence scale depending on the number of children in

    the household.13

    Then the problem is to make the optimal decision for consumption paths (Ct), the proportion

    of time spent accumulating human capital for each child (Ikt) and transfers to each child (Fk),

    considering future utility. Formally, equation (1) is specified as

    W(E+ A0) = maxCt,{Ikt},Fk

    T1t=0

    tu(Ct) + TB(AT, HT, F) (1

    )

    s.t. Ct (1 + (N)) + At+1 Et +Nk=1

    {(1 Ikt)RtHkt + IktRtHkt} + (1 + r)At

    (at t = 0,...,T 2)

    Ct (1 + (N)) +Nk=1

    Fk + At+1 Et +Nk=1

    {(1 Ikt)RtHkt + IktRtHkt} + (1 + r)At

    (at t = T 1).

    In terms of the process of human capital accumulation, I adopt a standard production function

    following Ben-Porath (1967) such that

    Ht+1 = (1 )Ht + 0(ItHt)1 , (2)

    where ItHt is effective time for human capital production, 0 > 0 is an ability parameter, 1 < 1

    reflects returns to scale and is the depreciation rate of human capital. The initial human

    13Deaton and Muellbauer (1986) introduce the concept of equivalence scale. The equivalence scale satisfies the

    following properties:

    (N) > 0 and

    (N) < 0.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    13/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 12

    capital level H0 > 0 is assumed to be exogenously given from parents educational attainment

    determined by the previous generation.

    Looking into the human capital production function and the budget constraint, there is a trade

    off between current labor earnings and accumulating more human capital. So the parents deci-

    sion is to determine when they should utilize childrens accumulated human capital. Additional

    accumulation of human capital of a child provides parents not only with more labor earnings

    when the child works, but also with positive utility for the parents old age.

    Next, the the economic agent in old age (from t = T,...,D) is described as follows. The problem

    faced in old age at time t = T is to find optimal consumption paths for the remainder of life. The

    total utility in this period includes the utility derived from the childs human capital. However,parents are assumed to have impure altruism which means they care less about the child than

    themselves: the utility derived from a childs income is discounted by .14 The sum of discounted

    utility from t = T onwards is

    B(AT, HT, F) = maxCt

    Dt=T

    tTu(Ct) + Nk=1

    W(RTHkT + Fk) (3)

    = b(AT) + Nk=1

    W(RTHkT + Fk)

    s.t. Ct + At+1 Et + (1 + r)At, t = T,...,D 1,

    CD = ED + (1 + r)AD, t = D,

    where (0, 1) is an altruism factor and W(RTHkT + Fk) is the utility that parents derivefrom the childs wealth. The continuation value from an optimal consumption decision for the

    rest of life in old age can be specified as b(AT), a function of asset level at time t = T. (See

    Appendix A for a derivation.)

    IIIb. Model Solution

    To solve the dynamic problem described above, I rewrite the problem in recursive form using

    the Bellman equations and solve it using backward induction. Note that the parents start an

    old phase of lives and child starts his or her own adulthood at time t = T. Given the value of T

    onwards, I solve the problem from the last period of parents decision at t = T1. At t = T1,

    parents decide the level of consumption, the fraction of time investment spent accumulating

    human capital and transfer to each child.

    14Aiyagari et al. (2002) also investigates the implication of impure altruism in terms of the effect on investment

    in childrens human capital and bequests.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    14/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 13

    Solutions at t=T-1

    The problem that the young parent faces at time T 1 is

    vT1(AT1, HT1, F) = maxAT,{HkT},{Fk}

    u(CT1) + {b(AT) + Nk=1

    W(RTHkT + Fk)}

    s.t. CT1 (1 + (N))+Nk=1

    Fk+AT ET1+Nk=1

    {(1IkT1)RT1HkT1+IkT1RT1HkT1}+(1+r)AT1.

    Since determining current time investment in human capital production is equivalent to deter-

    mining the next periods stock of human capital from the human capital production function, I

    solve the problem with respect to HkT instead of IkT1. Then the choice variables are HkT, Fkand AT, and the first order necessary conditions with respect to each of them are

    HkT :u(CT1)

    1 + (N)RT1HkT1(1 )

    IkT1

    HkT= RTW1(RTHkT + Fk) (4)

    Fk :u(CT1)

    1 + (N)= W1(RTHkT + Fk) (5)

    AT :u(CT1)

    1 + (N)= b1(AT). (6)

    Rearrange equation (4), replacingIkT1HkT

    from the production function of human capital.

    HkT :u(CT1)

    1 + (N)

    RT1(1 )

    01(

    HkT (1 )HkT10

    )111 = RTW1(RTHkT + Fk). (4)

    These equations present the simple rule of equating the marginal cost and benefit in determining

    each choice variable. The left hand side of equation (4) is the marginal cost of human capital

    accumulation, which is the utility loss from losing current earnings. The right hand side of it is

    the marginal benefit, which is the utility gain from the additional income of each child.

    The marginal cost of accumulating assets and making transfers to children are utility loss from

    giving up consumption. The marginal benefits of each are discounted utility from increased old

    age consumption and increased childrens income.

    Solutions at t=T-2,...,0

    The dynamic problem that the young adults face during t = 0,...,T 2, is

    vt(At, Ht, F) = max{Hkt+1},At+1

    u(Ct) + vt+1(At+1, Ht+1, F) (7)

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    15/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 14

    s.t. Ct (1 + (N)) + At+1 Et +Nk=1

    {(1 Ikt)RtHkt + IktRtHkt} + (1 + r)At, t = 0,...,T 2.

    The first order necessary conditions for each variable Ht+1 and At+1 are15

    Hkt+1 :u(Ct)

    1 + (N)

    (1 )Rt01

    (Hkt+1 (1 )Hkt

    0)

    111 = vHk,t+1(At+1, Ht+1, F) (8)

    At+1 :u(Ct)

    1 + (N)= vA,t+1(At+1, Ht+1, F). (9)

    The Envelope conditions are

    vHk,t(At, Ht, F) =u(Ct)Rt1 + (N)

    {1 +(1 )(1 )

    01(

    Hkt+1 (1 )Hkt0

    )111 } (10)

    vA,t(At, Ht, F) =u(Ct)(1 + r)

    1 + (N). (11)

    Combining equations (8) and (10) determines the solution for human capital, which is

    u(Ct)

    1 + (N)

    (1 )Rt0

    1

    (Hkt+1 (1 )Hkt

    0

    )111

    =u(Ct+1)Rt+1

    1 + (N){1 +

    (1 )(1 )

    01(

    Hkt+2 (1 )Hkt+10

    )111 }. (12)

    Similarly, combining equations (9) and (11) yields the familiar Euler equation,

    u(Ct) = (1 + r)u(Ct+1) (13)

    which simplifies equation (12) to16

    (1 + r)(1 )

    01 (

    Hkt+1 (1 )Hkt

    0 )

    111

    = 1+

    (1 )(1 )

    01 (

    Hkt+2 (1 )Hkt+1

    0 )

    111

    . (14)

    Equations (12) and (14) show that the marginal cost (benefit) of human capital accumulation

    is the loss (gain) of labor earnings that depends on educational attainment, and it should

    be expressed in terms of utility loss (gain) as in equation (12). With perfect capital markets,

    however, where the discounted marginal utility of consumption over time is constant, the decision

    is equivalent to equating the monetary marginal cost and benefit as in equation (14).

    15Let vHk,t(At,Ht, F) denote the partial derivative of value function vt(At,Ht, F) at t, with respect to Hkt.16Assume that Rt = R for all t.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    16/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 15

    IIIc. Model Implication and Comparative Statics

    There are two ways in which the educational decision described in the model may be considered

    as under-investment, which the government aims to improve with subsidies. First, parents

    investment in childrens human capital is less than the investment that the children would have

    made for themselves. Second, the borrowing constraint reduces the investment in human capital.

    Parents vs. Childrens Decision

    My model suggests that schooling decisions made by parents on behalf of children may not

    be optimal because the decisions are different from what would have been made by children

    themselves. The discrepancy between parents and childrens own decisions are larger when

    parents altruism is impure.

    Clearly, parents consider b(AT) + W(RTHkT + Fk) at time t = T 1 as a future value.Parents concern for childrens income is currently reflected only in W(RTHkT+ Fk). However,if children become the decision maker and their lifetime utility for the remainder of life are

    considered instead, then the educational attainment would be larger.17

    Thus, in the environment where parents use childrens earnings as a general source of income,

    parents decision on behalf of children for their human capital results in less education because

    parents do not fully consider childrens lifetime utility.

    Borrowing Constraints

    A borrowing constraint is another source of under-investment in childrens human capital. With-

    out borrowing constraints, the economic decision maker smoothes the consumption according

    to the Euler equation (13). However, if borrowing is constrained, the Euler equation holds only

    when At+1 > 0. Otherwise, u(Ct) > (1 + r)u

    (Ct+1), which implies the decision maker values

    current consumption more than discounted future consumption. Thus, the borrowing constraint

    increases current consumption and reduces future consumption by reducing educational invest-

    ment in children.17Specifically, the future value at t = T1 is kb(AT) +W(RTHkT, Fk), where k is the childs altruism toward

    parents. The lifetime utility for the remaining life for the child is W(RTHkT, Fk) = maxCt

    Dt=T

    tTu(Ct) with the

    budget constraint thatDt=T

    Ct(1+(Nk))

    (1+r)tT=

    Qt=T

    RTHT(1+r)tT

    +Fk, where Nk, D, and Q denote the number of children,

    end of life, and retirement of the child, respectively. If the childs altruism toward parents is negligible, and the

    curvatures ofW andW are same, the marginal utility of accumulating additional human capital is much greaterin the childs decision than in parents.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    17/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 16

    Hkt+1Hkt+1H

    kt+1

    RHS

    LHS

    Figure 1: Determination of Human Capital Stock

    the effect of a borrowing constraint

    Figure 1 illustrates the human capital accumulation with and without borrowing constraint.

    The two curves present the monetary marginal cost of human capital accumulation (LHS: lefthand side) and marginal benefit (RHS: right hand side) in equation (14).18 Without borrowing

    constraint, equating monetary cost and benefit determines optimal human capital at Hkt+1.

    However, when borrowing constraint is imposed and u(Ct) > (1 + r)u(Ct+1), satisfying equa-

    tion (12) requires greater monetary benefit in the next period to compensate for the lower utility

    of consumption. Thus the optimal level is reduced to Hkt+1.

    As suggested above, parents investment in childrens human capital falls short of the optimal

    level and the under-investment is worsened due to the credit constraints. I will examine the

    18When 1 > 0.5, it is shown thatLHSHkt+1

    > 0 and 2LHS

    H2

    kt+1

    < 0, and RHSHkt+1< 0 and

    2RHSH2

    kt+1

    < 0 by the

    following equations:

    LHS

    Hkt+1=

    (1 + r)(1 )(1 1)

    (01)2(Hkt+1 (1 )Hkt

    0)1/12

    2LHS

    H2kt+1=

    (1 + r)(1 )(1 1)(1 21)

    (01)3(Hkt+1 (1 )Hkt

    0)1/13

    RHS

    Hkt+1=(1 )2(1 1)(1 )

    (01)2(Hkt+2 (1 )Hkt+1

    0)1/12

    2RHS

    H2kt+1=

    (1 )(1 )3(1 1)(1 21)

    (01)3(Hkt+2 (1 )Hkt+1

    0)1/13

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    18/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 17

    comparative statics of key variables how the credit constraints affect the households decision

    according to these key variables. First, I consider family size because family size reflects theextent to which a household is borrowing constrained. Second, I visit the familiar question of

    gender gap in education and investigates what my model implies about it. Third, I investigate

    the effects of constraints according to the ability of a child.

    Family Size: Number of Children (N)

    Equation (14) indicates that the decision on human capital is not affected by the consumption

    level or the number of children in the household when there is no borrowing constraint. The size

    of household only matters when there is a borrowing constraint. Increasing the number of chil-

    dren is costly in households consumption and makes the household more borrowing constrained,

    although children may contribute earnings to the household as they get older.

    My model suggests that children from larger families have lower educational attainment because

    these households are more borrowing constrained and the opportunity cost of accumulating

    human capital for these households is greater. This implication will be empirically tested and

    discussed.

    Gender: Rental Rate for Human Capital (Rt) and Altruism Factor ()

    As shown in Table 3, there is a slight difference in the school enrollment rate across gender.

    Encouraging female childrens schooling by providing a slightly higher subsidy is to remedy this

    lower investment in female children. In the model, there are two sources that can induce different

    allocations between genders: the rental rate for human capital and the different altruism factor

    toward each child.

    The rental rate for human capital Rt is the price of it. Although human capital and the rental

    rate are not observable, the wages must reflect the total price for the stock of human capital paid

    in the labor market. It is easy to think that the higher rental rate for human capital might induce

    more human capital accumulation. However, since the higher rental rate for human capital also

    means the higher opportunity cost of human capital accumulation, whether the higher rentalrate results in greater investment in human capital is not obvious.

    Meanwhile, the greater altruism factor in this model seems to imply greater transfer from

    parents to the child and greater investment in human capital of the child. Combining equation

    (5) and (6) clearly shows that greater altruism factor implies greater transfer to the child. The

    effect of altruism factor on human capital accumulation, however, is not so straightforward.

    Equations (4) and (5) show that the different altruism factor does not make a difference in

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    19/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 18

    human capital accumulation as long as parents make a transfer to the child.19 When excluding

    the case that parents receive a reverse transfer from children, then the altruism factor makes adifference, with smaller altruism resulting in lower investment in human capital.

    The price for human capital is the shadow price of education. Although it is not obvious whose

    rental rate for human capital is valued higher, the difference in rental rate for human capital

    between gender can induce different educational investment. In addition, difference in parents

    altruism toward each gender of children would make difference. In particular, attention has been

    paid to whether the difference in educational outcome by gender is due to difference in parents

    altruism.(e.g. Behrman et al. (1986)) In the empirical test, I will revisit this issue.

    Ability: The Ability Factor (0)

    In the model, one of the most important factors that affect the parents decision about human

    capital is the ability of a child. The childs ability determines the productivity of accumulating

    human capital. A higher-ability child is able to accumulate human capital faster with the same

    time input than a lower-ability one. Then, combined with the larger stock of human capital

    accumulated, the higher-ability child can accelerate human capital accumulation.

    The greater the childs ability, the higher the accumulated human capital and the steeper the

    human capital accumulation. Then the household with a higher-ability child receives more

    earnings from the child as the child gets older compared to the household with lower-abilitychild. This means that the consumption smoothing requires more resources for households with

    higher-ability child than the other counterpart. Therefore, when the households income is low

    and there is a borrowing constraint, the households with higher-ability would be disadvantaged

    further by the credit constraint and poverty.20

    Without a borrowing constraint, it is obvious from the equation (14) that the time investment in

    human capital accumulation is monotonic to the ability of a child: a higher-ability child spends

    more time accumulating human capital. However, with a borrowing constraint, this relationship

    is no longer apparent. Since a higher-ability child has a higher opportunity cost of accumulating

    human capital, the higher-ability child may leave quicker for labor market. Thus, whether time

    investment is monotonic to the childs ability over his or her entire childhood is not obvious.

    19Equations (5) and (6) gives W1(RTHkT + Fk)=b1(AT), and equations (4) and (5) gives(1)01

    (HkT(1)HkT1

    0)111 = 1. These equations hold only when the amount of transfer from parents to

    the child is positive.20Numerically, the ratio of marginal utility of current and future consumption for households with a higher-

    ability and a low-ability child shows the inequality as [ u(Ct)

    u(Ct+1)]H > [

    u(Ct)u(Ct+1)

    ]L. Then the reduction in human

    capital accumulation is greater for a higher-ability child as shown in the Figure 1.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    20/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 19

    In this section, I have presented the model and the solution for it, which determines households

    educational investment in children. The model implies that parents educational decision forchildren is not optimal. The extent to which the sources of parents under-investment reduces

    education varies with the family size, gender, and ability of the child. Throughout next sections

    of calibration and estimation, these implications will be examined, and the differential subsidy

    effects according to these key variables will be investigated.

    IV. Calibration

    Having considered some implications of the factors that affect childrens education, I calibrate

    the model to further investigate the effects of each factor, its magnitude and the effects of the

    subsidy. Thus, in this section, I parameterize the model, assume specific functional forms, and

    present the findings from the model.

    IVa. Subsidy Effects

    Assume utility is CRRA: i.e., u(Ct) =C1t1 and

    W(RTHkT + Fk) = (RTHkT+Fk)11 . The modelis calibrated using the following parameter values summarized in Table 5.

    Table 5: Benchmark Parameter Values.

    Preferences

    -Discount Factor, = 0.96

    -CRRA: Consumption, = 2.0

    -CRRA: Childs Income, = 2.0

    -Altruism Factor, = 0.3

    Production Function

    -Ability, 0 log N(, 2)

    = 0.1, = 0.3

    0 = 0.52, 0.70, 0.95, 1.28, 1.73, 2.34

    -Return to Scale, 1 = 0.73

    -Initial Human Capital, H0 = 100

    -Depreciation Rate, = 0.0

    Period of Analysis

    -Beginning of Old Age at T, T = 43

    -Retirement at Q, Q = 65

    -Death at D, D = 75

    Educational Subsidy-Subsidy Rate, = 0.20

    -Subsidized Ages of a Child, Age 16

    Other Parameters-Gross Interest Rate, r = 1.06

    -Equivalence Scale, = 1.05

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    21/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 20

    Preferences: The time period of the model is a year and the time discount rate is set at 0.96.

    For the CRRA utility functions, let the coefficient of relative risk aversion of consumption,,

    assume a standard value of 2.0 and the coefficient for human capital stock, , start with 2.0.21

    Since there is no theoretical or empirical grounds for the altruism factor, which measures how

    much parents care about a childs wealth relative to their own utility, let be set to 0.3.22

    Human Capital Production: Assume that 0, which is the parameter of ability, is distributed

    as log normal; i.e., log 0 N(, 2). Setting = 0.1 and = 0.3, I calibrate the model

    at 6 different levels of ability ranging from 0.52 to 2.34.23 The estimate for the depreciation

    rate and returns to scale parameter varies. For example, Heckman (1976) found the estimate

    of the Ben-Porath model and his own model gives 0.81 and 0.52 for 1, and 0.09 and 0.04 for

    depreciation rate , respectively. I will begin with 1 = 0.73 and = 0.0. For the benchmark

    case, the initial human capital is homogenous for everyone.

    Period of Analysis: I assume that the agent is a young parent between the ages of 23 and

    43. During this period, between the childs ages of 6 and 22, parents make decisions on time

    investment in accumulating human capital for children as well their own consumption and asset

    accumulation. At the parents age of 43, when the child turns into young adult and leaves the

    natal household, the parents enter the phase of old age. In this phase, they have a positive

    earnings stream until they retire at age 65.

    Educational Subsidy: The PROGRESA subsidy is provided to children who enroll in school

    when they are between the third year of primary school to the third year of secondary school.

    Therefore, in this simulation, I assume the subsidy is provided for children younger than 16,

    which is the corresponding age for PROGRESA. The subsidy rate is fixed at 20% for all ages.

    Other Parameters: The real interest rate is set at 6%.24 The equivalence scale is set as a

    concave function of the number of children in the household. Thus, for a three child household,

    the = 1.05.25

    21There are few literature that estimated the coefficient of relative risk aversion (the reciprocal of the intertem-

    poral elasticity of substitution) using Mexican data. According to the summary in Reinhart and Talvi (1998), the

    intertemporal elasticity of substitution in Latin American countries including Mexico range from 0.43 to 0.56.22Since there is no standard number for altruism factor, 0.3 is used for illustrative purpose. The effect of impure

    altruism of parents on a childs human capital accumulation by changing altruism factor will be discussed.23This covers 2.5 standard deviations from the mean.24According to the report by the Ministry of Finance and Public Credit of Mexico, the real interest rate in 1997

    was about 6%.25If the consumption is same for all three children, that = 1.05 implies that a child consumes 35% of parents

    consumption. Considering that parents are two adults, the consumption of one child in three children household

    is equivalent to 70% of an adults consumption.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    22/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 21

    Table 6: Years of Schooling by Age: Data and Simulation Comparison

    Years of Schooling Age 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

    Without Data 1.12 1.75 2.55 3.32 4.10 4.81 5.41 5.95 6.05 6.10

    PROGRESA Simulation 0.95 1.78 2.52 3.21 3.86 4.47 5.06 5.63 6.16 6.45

    With Data 1.35 1.92 2.64 3.37 4.25 5.03 5.84 6.42 6.80 7.12

    PROGRESA Simulation 0.89 1.81 2.74 3.58 4.37 5.12 5.83 6.53 7.11 7.49

    Table 6 shows the average years of schooling for each age for the PROGRESA data and simula-

    tion, comparing data for children without and with the subsidy program. The subsidy increases

    the average years of schooling in each age. The increase appears to be especially greater for the

    older children between the ages of fourteen and sixteen. The results from the simulation show a

    model prediction of years of schooling with and without the PROGRESA subsidy, and predicts

    the similar effect of the subsidy on years of schooling as observed in the data.

    6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 220

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    Childs Age

    Time

    Time Investment in Human Capital Accumulation

    Without Subsidy

    With Subsidy

    6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 220

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200

    Human Capital Accumulation

    Childs Age

    HumanC

    apital

    With Subsidy

    WIthout Subsidy

    Figure 2. The Effects of Subsidy:

    Time Investment and Human Capital Accumulation

    Figure 2 presents the outcomes of time investment and human capital accumulation paths of

    the ages of children, and compares these outcomes with and without the subsidy.26 As shown in

    the figure, the increase in time investment is significant while the subsidy is provided until the

    26For the comparison of these outcomes in the case without credit constraint and with parents pure altruism,

    see Appendix B. It discusses the source of inefficiency that results in under-investment and thus provides the

    rationale for governmental intervention. Moreover, the paths of assets and human capital accumulation, and time

    investment in human capital production are presented.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    23/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 22

    age of 16, after which the reduction in time investment is steep. The overall increase in human

    capital due to the subsidy and thus the increase in labor earnings is around 19%.

    The introduction of subsidy increases schooling and human capital accumulation. In terms of

    evaluating what the increase in human capital implies and whether the subsidy rate is optimal,

    I will consider two ways to quantify the effects. The first is in terms of the cost and benefits of

    the subsidy program and the other is by the comparison to the human capital achieved in an

    ideal economy without either borrowing constraints or without impure altruism.

    IVb. Benefits and Costs of the Subsidy Program

    Based on the simulations, I calculate the benefits and costs of PROGRESA. The benefits of

    increasing human capital accumulation as a result of subsidy are from two sources. One is the

    present discounted value of the increase in earnings contributed to the household due to the

    introduction of the subsidy. The second is the present discounted value of the increase in the

    lifetime earnings of the child.27 The costs of the subsidy is simply the present discounted value

    of the subsidy amounts provided to households.28

    The simulations show that with a subsidy rate of 20%, the benefits of the program exceeds the

    cost by 60%.29 The benefit-cost ratio is higher for children from larger families, implying that

    the subsidy is more effective for those children.

    IVc. Comparison to a No Credit Constraint and Pure Altruism Case

    In addition, I examine whether PROGRESA can raise human capital to the level that could

    have been obtained in an economy without credit constraint and with pure altruism.30

    On average, the subsidy increases human capital accumulation, although the extent to which

    the level of human capital becomes closer to the outcome of the no constraint case varies by

    the ability and family size of the child. The lower-ability children and children from smaller

    families achieve even greater human capital by the introduction of the subsidy than what they

    27

    There can be indirect b enefits of subsidizing and increasing education. For example, Barnett (1992) calculatebenefits of early education using five types of benefits including the value of child care and reduction in the costs

    of crime. However, I consider main benefits of education which increases household income and lifetime earnings.28There must b e administrative costs related to implementing this program. However, for this calculation,

    subsidies provided to households are only included to the costs of the program.29The lifetime earnings are calculated assuming that the individuals make the same level of labor earnings from

    the age of 23 onwards until they retire at age 65, with the real interest rate fixed at 6%.30Note that this idealistic environment with no credit constraint and pure altruism does not mean that there

    is no under-investment at all. Parents are still making decision on behalf of children without full consideration

    of childrens lifetime utility. Although parents utility from altruistic motive captures parents concern about

    childrens lifetime utility, it is not necessarily same with childrens own lifetime utility.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    24/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 23

    could have achieved without constraint, while the human capital accumulation of higher-ability

    children and children from larger families fall short. The overall level of human capital is shortof the no constraint level by 8%.

    The effect of subsidy is different across households and individuals. The effect would be greatest

    for those households which are borrowing constrained without any subsidy and become not

    constrained with subsidy, since the negative effect of borrowing constraint on education is huge.31

    Considering this, the effects on marginal households would be greater and the subsidy has a

    greater impact on children from larger family on average, since the larger families are more

    likely to be on the margin than the smaller families.

    In summary, through this calibration, my model replicates the observed schooling decisions andthe effects of the program. The results show that the subsidy increases overall years of schooling

    and, thus, human capital accumulation. The benefit of the subsidy, by increasing education,

    exceeds the cost of the subsidy when the lifetime effect of increase in earnings are taken into

    account. The magnitudes of the effects are not uniform: the magnitude depends on various

    factors including to what extent households are credit constrained. The model implies that the

    effect of subsidy is greater for children from larger families.

    V. An Empirical Test

    In this section, I test whether the effect of PROGRESA is greater for larger families. In addition,

    I examine gender differences in schooling. First, I test whether the gender difference in educa-

    tional attainment is due to parental preferences. Second, I investigate the effects of subsidy on

    both genders.

    Va. Family Size and Subsidy Effects

    If the credit markets were perfect, the educational attainment of children would be the same

    across households regardless of family size. However, with borrowing constraints, children in

    larger families are not able to attend school for as long a period of time as children in smallerfamilies. Increasing the number of children in the household is costly, which implies that bor-

    rowing constraints are more severe in these families. Thus educational attainment is lower for

    children from larger families, other things equal.

    However, when the subsidies are introduced, their effects are expected to be greater for larger

    families. In other words, for a child in a smaller family who would have attended school regard-

    less of the subsidy program, since those households are not greatly borrowing constrained, the

    31Recall the effect of borrowing constraint on time investment and human capital accumulation from Appendix

    B.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    25/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 24

    subsidy does not greatly affect the schooling decision. However, a child in larger family may

    now be able to attend school due to the introduction of the subsidy, otherwise the child wouldnot have been able to attend school. In that sense, the effects of subsidy are expected to be

    greater for children from larger families. From the simulation, it is also shown that the effect of

    the subsidy is greater for these children.

    To test this hypothesis, the following equation of school attendance is specified and estimated

    with the experimental data. Let sit indicate school attendance at time t for individual i. The

    event of attending school (st = 1), is determined by a latent variable st , which can be explained

    by individual, family, and locality characteristics. In other words,

    sit = xit + i + it (15)

    sit = {1 if sit > 0

    0 if sit 0, i = 1,...,N, t = 1,...,T

    where xit denotes the characteristics of individual i, at time t, it is unobservable individual

    heterogeneity and it is white noise. Since this individual heterogeneity (i) is unobservable,

    it is considered as a individual random variable. Thus, the random effects logit regression is

    estimated.32 Because the data set is a panel, following the same individuals over time, I estimate

    the equation controlling for the unobservable characteristics (i).

    The individual characteristics include age, gender and the indicator of the eldest child of each

    gender. Family characteristics include a measurement of parents education level and the age

    of the youngest child. As a variable showing the family size, the number of adults and dummy

    variables for the number of children are included. The characteristics of the locality include the

    presence of a primary school and a secondary school within the locality, and the local wage rate

    for child labor at each age.

    To capture the effects of the program, I include the indicator of program locality, eligible house-

    holds, and the indicator of the time when the program began. Finally, the differential effects

    of the program on households with different numbers of children are reflected in the variable of

    the interaction between indicators of program locality, eligible households and after the programonset.

    The summary statistics of the variables which are used in this analysis and the results from the

    random effects logistic regression are presented in Tables C1 through C3 in the Appendix. The

    32The conditional distribution of this variable conditioning on other observable variables are assumed to

    follow normal distribution: G(i|xit) N(0, 2). Then the conditional probability of schooling specified as

    Pr(sit = 1|xit, i) = F(

    xit + i) where F satisfies F(w) =ew

    1+ew. Then the log likelihood function is

    log L =Ni=1

    log Tt=1

    F(

    xit + i)sit{1 F(

    xit + i)}1sitdG(|x). According to Heckmans the Monte Carlo

    experiments, the fixed effect estimate for the parameters is not consistent when T is finite. (Heckman(1981))

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    26/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 25

    Table 7: Random Effects Logit Regression-Family Size.

    (1) (2)

    Variables Coefficient S.E. Variables Coefficient S.E.

    N=1 (dropped) Poor*N=1 -1.056 (0.217)

    N=2 0.243 (0.127) Poor*N=2 -0.785 (0.186)

    N=3 -0.029 (0.129) Poor*N=3 -0.903 (0.184)

    N=4 0.071 (0.133) Poor*N=4 -0.757 (0.173)

    N=5 0.005 (0.137) Poor*N=5 -0.761 (0.176)

    N6 -0.312 (0.138) Poor*N6 -0.984 (0.184)

    Treat*After 0.024 (0.070) Treat*After*Poor 0.574 (0.150)

    Treat*After*N=1 -0.141 (0.166) Treat*After*Poor*N=2 0.091 (0.197)

    Treat*After*N=3 0.482 (0.124) Treat*After*Poor*N=3 0.408 (0.188)

    Treat*After*N=4 0.309 (0.121) Treat*After*Poor*N=4 0.246 (0.183)

    Treat*After*N=5 0.320 (0.123) Treat*After*Poor*N=5 0.269 (0.184)

    Treat*After*N6 0.547 (0.114) Treat*After*Poor*N6 0.451 (0.178)

    *, **, *** significant at 10%, 5% and 1% confidence levels.

    results are consistent with intuition: School attendance decreases with the age of a child. The

    higher the household heads education, the more likely the child is to attend school; The eldest

    and female child is disadvantaged in schooling; The more adults in the household, the less school

    attendance for the child; The locality characteristics also have a great effect on schooling. The

    localities where there are primary and secondary schools and localities with lower local wage

    rates for child labor, have higher school enrollment.

    The effects of the subsidy on families of different sizes are presented in Table 7. The first

    specification analyzes the effect of PROGRESA on the localities of the program after it starts.

    The results show that the child from families with six children or more has significantly lower

    school enrollment compared to the child from one child family. The effects of subsidy program

    on the school enrollment of children in program localities, presented in the bottom panel of thetable, are significantly greater for children from larger families.

    Since only eligible (poor) households receive cash transfers from the PROGRESA program, even

    though the entire program locality benefits from indirect supports of the program, the second

    specification captures the programs effect only on eligible (poor) households. Compared to

    non-poor households with each number of children, poor households show significantly lower

    school attendance of children.

    The bottom panel shows the effects of subsidy on the school enrollment of children in eligible

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    27/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 26

    (poor) households in program localities after the program starts. There is an overall significant

    increase in school enrollment for these children. The effects are shown to be larger for childrenfrom 3 child families and 6 or more child families, compared to children from one child families.

    The results from both specifications consistently show that the effects vary with the size of the

    family. Although the school attendance of children from larger families is significantly lower than

    that of smaller families, the effects of subsidies are greater for families with a larger number of

    children. This suggests that the PROGRESA subsidy mitigates the negative effect of the number

    of children in the household and thus the credit constraints.

    Vb. Gender and Subsidy Effects

    In this section, I examine whether parents have unequal concern by gender, and whether this

    causes different educational outcomes between the genders. According to my model, differences

    in educational attainment of children between genders can be due to two factors: rental rate for

    human capital and parents altruism factor. The fact that men and women with the same level

    of education make different labor earnings (Recall Table 4.) suggests that there is difference in

    the rental rate of human capital by gender.

    However, there is little evidence that parents have unequal concern for children of different

    gender. The expenditure on clothes and shoes of female and male children, which is often

    used as measure that reflects parents altruism toward the children of each gender, shows thatthe households spend about the same proportion of the entire expenditure for children of each

    gender; 24.8% for male children and 23.9% for female children on average.33 Therefore, whether

    parents altruism differs towards children of each gender is not obvious.

    The hypothesis to be tested is that the school enrollment of female children from households with

    only female children should be different from that of households with male and female children,

    if what makes a difference in school attendance of children across gender is parents preference.

    I again estimate random effects logistic regression for school enrollment of female children.

    The empirical specification is similar to equation (15). The indicator of female-children-only

    households interacted with poverty status is included to reflect differences that might be due to

    the parents altruism. The following table shows the results from the equation.34

    The results show that there is no significant differences in school enrollment of female children

    in households with only female children compared to children in households with female and

    33Data source: PROGRESA 1998 household survey34See Table C4 in the Appendix for the complete results.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    28/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 27

    Table 8: Random Effects Logit Regression-Gender (1).

    Variables Coefficient S.E.

    Female Only 0.003 (0.183)

    Female Only*Poor -0.264 (0.203)

    Treat*After*Poor 0.953 (0179)

    Treat*After*Poor*Female Only -0.020 (0.107)

    *, **, *** significant at 10%, 5% and 1% confidence levels.

    male children.35 The outcome of female children in poor households with only female children

    is not different from that of female children in poor households with female and male children.

    In terms of the subsidy effect, there is no significantly different effect on female children in both

    types of households.

    In addition, the effects of the subsidy on children of each gender is investigated. Since the

    subsidy rate for older female children is higher, while the rate is the same for both genders of

    younger children, the effects of subsidy on school attendance of older female children should be

    larger than the effects for older male children, while the effects on younger children are expected

    not to differ by gender.36

    Table 9: Random Effects Logit Regression-Gender (2).

    Variables Coefficient S.E.

    Female -0.020 (0.817)

    Older Female -0.405 (0.198)

    Treat*After*Poor 1.696 (0.159)

    Treat*After*Poor*Female -0.186 (0.131)

    Treat*After*Poor*Older*Female 0.601 (0.184)

    *, **, *** significant at 10%, 5% and 1% confidence levels.

    As presented in Table 9, the school enrollment is much lower for older female children.37 The

    effects of the subsidy program is consistently found to be positive and significant. The effect

    of the subsidy on school enrollment of female children is not significantly different from that of

    35Note that this regression estimates only female childrens school enrollment. The number of observations

    used for this regression is 50,368 which is about half of the total observation in data. The proportion of female

    children in households with only female children is 38%, and the other 62% of female children are in households

    with female and male chilren.36Older children refer to those who are over 12 years old and corresponds to the secondary school level.37See Table C5 in the Appendix for the complete results.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    29/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 28

    male children. However, the subsidy significantly increases the school attendance of older female

    children.

    VI. Policy Experiments

    Having investigated the households investment in childrens human capital and the effect of

    the educational subsidy program using PROGRESA, policy implications are now considered.

    Specifically, simulations with alternative subsidy schedules are examined to consider alternative

    policies that might be more effective.

    Va. Subsidy Varying by Ability

    In the previous calibration of the benchmark model, the subsidy rate is fixed at 20% for all

    children. The reason why the policy makers should implement a higher subsidy rate for higher-

    ability children is that higher-ability children are more disadvantaged by credit constraints.38

    In this exercise, for the lower-half of children by ability distribution is subsidized at the rate

    of 15% and the other half is subsidized at the rate of 25%. The cost and benefits of this new

    subsidy schedule is compared to the benchmark case. A higher subsidy rate for higher-ability

    children increases cost of subsidy by 70%, while the benefit of the subsidy increases by 87%.

    Thus, the ratio of benefit to cost of this subsidy slightly increases, meaning that ability-basedscholarship is more effective in terms of benefit and cost aspect.

    Since the government is not able to observe individual childs ability, the merit-based subsidy

    such as larger scholarship for children with better test scores might be implementable.39

    Vb. Subsidy Varying by Family Size

    A higher subsidy rate for larger families is more effective than a flat subsidy rules, because the

    effects of subsidies are greater for children in larger families. Considering that children from

    larger families are more disadvantaged by borrowing constraint, the greater subsidy for them

    seems justifiable.

    Although I find that the subsidy rate varying by family size is more effective, it may not be

    practically implementable. It is currently assumed that the family size is exogenous. However,

    38The reduction in education due to a borrowing constraint is greater for higher-ability children and children

    from larger families. In that sense, they are more disadvantaged by credit constraint. See Appendix B again for

    the effect of borrowing constraints.39The data of childrens school performance such as test scores are not available at the period of analysis.

    Examining the effects of the PROGRESA subsidy on school performance across children with different test scores

    can be a subject for further research.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    30/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 29

    considering that a family size and fertility are also decisions that the household makes, greater

    subsidies for larger families might cause people to have additional children which would resultin more credit constraint.40

    VII. Conclusion

    In this study, I quantitatively assess the effect of PROGRESA on the education of the children.

    I develop a dynamic model of household behavior to determine how parents determine childrens

    schooling. My model shows that parents who rely on childrens earnings for household consump-

    tion, and either face the credit constraints or have impure altruism toward children, under-invest

    in childrens human capital. The educational subsidy contingent on school attendance reduces

    the problem of under-investment.

    The educational subsidy program aims to achieve the goal of increasing human capital accumu-

    lation in an effective and efficient way. I evaluate the program in two ways. First, I analyze the

    benefits and costs of the subsidy. Second, I investigate the increase in human capital induced by

    a subsidy, and whether this increase is large enough to achieve human capital that could have

    been achieved without credit constraints and with purely altruistic preferences.

    I find that PROGRESA increases average years of schooling by one year and human capitalaccumulation by 19%. Higher-ability children and children from larger families are disadvantaged

    and obtain less human capital than compared to an economy without borrowing constraints and

    with pure altruism. Although the subsidy increases the human capital, it falls short of the

    unconstrained level. And this shortage is even greater for higher-ability children and children

    from larger families. From a benefit-cost perspective, the benefit of PROGRESA exceeds the

    cost at the current subsidy rate.

    The model implies that the subsidy has greater a effect on children from larger families. I test

    whether the PROGRESA data are consistent with this implication of my model. I find the effect

    of subsidy on school enrollment is greater for the children from larger families. The model also

    suggests that parents impure altruism reduces childrens schooling when a borrowing constraint

    exists. I reject the hypothesis that the difference in schooling of children by gender is due to

    the difference in parental altruism toward them. The effects of the subsidy are not significantly

    different by gender when the children is in primary school. Due to the higher subsidy rate for

    older female children, the effect is greater for older female than older male children.

    40For this reason, PROGRESA impose maximum amount of subsidy to the households, which does not exceeds

    three times of the per child amount of subsidy

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    31/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 30

    My model shows that parents decision on schooling on behalf of their children is not optimal

    because it is different from what children would have make if they made on their own. Theborrowing constraint and impure altruism reduces education even further. The government,

    therefore, has incentive to intervene to remedy the under-investment. I examine policy exper-

    iments that provide varying subsidy rates according to ability and family size. I find that a

    larger subsidy for higher-ability children and children from larger families are more effective in

    both increasing human capital.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    32/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 31

    References

    Adato, M., B. Briere, D. Mindek and A. Quisumbing (2000). The Impact of Progresa

    on Womens Status and Intrahousehold Relations, International Food Policy Research Institute,

    Washington, D.C.

    Aiyagari, S., J, Greenwood, and A. Seshadri (2002). Efficient Investment in Children,

    Journal of Economic Theory, 102(2), 290-321.

    Altonji, J., and T. Dunn (1996). The Effects of Family characteristics on the Return to

    Education, Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(4), 692-704.

    Attanasio, O., C. Meghir and A. Santiago (2001). Education Choices in Mexico:Using a Structural Model and a Randomized Experiment to Evaluate Progresa, Inter-American

    Development Bank, Washington, D.C.

    Barnett, W. (1992).Benefits of Compensatory Preschool Education, Journal Human Re-

    sources, 27(2), 279-312.

    Becker, G., and N. Tomes (1986).Human Capital and the Rise and Fall of Families,

    Journal of Labor Economics, 3(4), S1-S39.

    Behrman, J., R. Pollak, and P. Taubman (1982). Parental Preferences and Provision

    for Progeny, Journal of Political Economy, 90(1), 52-73.

    Behrman, J., R. Pollak, and P. Taubman (1986). Do Parents Favor Boys?, Interna-

    tional Economic Review, 27(1), 33-54.

    Behrman, J., P. Sengupta, and P. Todd (2001). Progressing through PROGRESA: An

    Impact Assessment of a School Subsidy Experiment, April. University of Pennsylvania and the

    International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.

    Behrman, J. and P. Todd (1999). Randomness in the Experimental Samples of PRO-

    GRESA (Education, Health, and Nutrition Program), International Food Policy Research In-

    stitute, Washington, D.C.

    Ben-Porath, Y. (1967). The Production Function of Human Capital and the Life Cycle of

    Earnings, Journal of Political Economy, 75(4), part 1, 352-365.

    Cameron, S. and C. Taber (2000). Borrowing Cnstraints and the Returns to Schooling,

    NBER Working Paper #7761.

    Card, D. (1999). The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings in O. Ashenfelter, and D.

    Card, eds., Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol 3A. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland,

    1801-1863.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    33/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 32

    Deaton, A. and J. Muellbauer (1986). On Measuring Child Costs: With Application to

    Poor Countries, Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), part 1, 720-744.Gould, B. and H. Villarreal (2002). Adult Equivalence Scales and Food Expenditures:

    an Application to Mexican Beef and Pork Purchases, Applied Economics 34, 1075-1088.

    Griliches, Z. (1977). Estimating the Returns to Schooling: Some Econometric Problems,

    Econometrica 45(1), 1-22.

    Heckman, J. (1976). A Life-Cycle Model of Earnings, Learning, and Consumption, Journal

    of Political Economy 84(4), S11-S44.

    Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error, Econometrica 47(1),

    153-161.

    Heckman, J. (1981). The Incidental Parameters Problem and the Problem of Initial Con-

    ditions in Estimating a Discrete Time-Discrete Data Stochastic Process in Structural Analysis

    of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications, edited by C.F. Manski and D. McFadden, pp.

    179-195. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Keane, M. and K. Wolpin (1997). The Career Decisions of Young Men, Journal of

    Political Economy 105(3), 473-522.

    Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings, New York: NBER.

    Pollak, R. (2002). Gary Beckers Contribution to Family and Household Economics, NBER

    Working Paper #9232.

    Reinhart, C. and E. Talvi (1998). Capital Flows and Saving in Latin America and Asia:

    A Reinterpretation, Journal of Development Economics, 57(1), 45-66

    Schultz, P. (2000). School Subsidies for the Poor: Evaluating the Mexican Strategy for

    Reducing Poverty, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.

    Schultz, P. (2001). School Subsidies for the Poor: Evaluating the Mexican Progresa Poverty

    Program, Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper, # 834.

    Skoufias, E., B. Davis and J. Behrman (1999). An Evaluation of the Selection of

    Beneficiary Households in the Education, Health, and Nutrition Program (PROGRESA) of

    Mexico, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.

    Todd, P. and K. Wolpin (2003). Using a Social Experiment to Validate a Dynamic

    Behavioral Model of Child Schooling and Fertility: Assessing the Impact of a School Subsidy

    Program in Mexico, PIER Working Papers, University of Pennsylvania.

    Wills, R. (1986). Wage Determinants: A Survey and Reinterpretation of Human Capital

    Earnings Functions in O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard, eds. Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol.

    1, Chapter 10. New York: North Holland.

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    34/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 33

    Appendix

    A. Solution for Old Age

    For old age, the following assumptions are made: 1) parents have no bequest motive nor are

    they able to leave their offspring a debt. 2) There is no uncertainty about their retirement, Q,

    and death, D. By imposing these assumptions, the borrowing constraint is no longer binding as

    long as the asset at t = T is positive. Then the continuation value of parents b(AT) is equivalent

    to

    b(AT) = maxCt

    Dt=T

    tTu(Ct)

    s.t.

    Dt=T

    Ct

    (1 + r)tT=

    Qt=T

    Et

    (1 + r)tT+ (1 + r)AT. (A1)

    By the Euler equation, u(Ct ) = (1 + r)u(Ct+1), and u

    (Ct) = Ct , the following equation

    holds for k = 0,...,D T

    CT+k = {(1 + r)}k/CT.

    Using this equation which holds for optimal consumption, CT is derived as a function of AT

    from the budget constraint (equation (A1)), so that

    CT

    DTk=0

    {(1 + r)}k/

    (1 + r)k=

    Qt=T

    Et

    (1 + r)tT+ (1 + r)AT

    equivalently,

    CT =

    Qt=T

    Et(1+r)tT

    + (1 + r)AT

    DTk=0

    {(1+r)}k/

    (1+r)k

    . (A2)

    Meanwhile, the Bellman equation for the old age problem is written as

    b(AT) = maxCT

    u(CT) + b(AT+1)

    s.t.

    Dt=T

    Ct

    (1 + r)tT=

    Qt=T

    Et

    (1 + r)tT+ (1 + r)AT. (A3)

  • 7/27/2019 Yoon 1019

    35/42

    Human Capital and Schooling 34

    The Envelope condition gives a following equation.

    b1(AT) = (1 + r)u(CT).

    Then, by replacing CT with equation (A2), the first derivative of the value function of old age

    with respect to asset level, b1(AT), is found.

    B. Outcomes under a Perfect Capital Market and with Pure Altruism

    This section presents the outcome of household assets and childrens human capital accumula-

    tion, and time investment paths assuming a perfect capital market and parents pure altruism.

    By projecting the outco