Transcript
Page 1: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

Institute for International Political Economy Berlin

Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation

Authors: Marta Kulesza

Working Paper, No. 93/2017

Editors: Sigrid Betzelt Trevor Evans Eckhard Hein Hansjörg Herr Birgit Mahnkopf Christina Teipen Achim Truger Markus Wissen

Page 2: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract
Page 3: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation*

Marta Kulesza

Abstract This paper aims to explain the causes of rapidly increasing prices in Venezuela and establish whether the current episode can be considered to be of hyperinflationary nature from the post-Keynesian theoretical approach. The chosen approach highlights the role of distributive conflict, indexation mechanism, balance of payments constraint, devaluation expectations and gradual rejection of national currency in favour of foreign currency. We argue that the root cause of the precarious economic situation in Venezuela lies in the long term failure to implement structural changes, ensuring industrial diversification and lessening the dependency on oil exports. The symptoms of the Dutch disease are observed in the prolonged currency overvaluation during the high oil revenue periods. In the face of a growing external constraint, the authorities introduce severe foreign currency rationing. This in turn ignites inflation due to external bottlenecks since many sectors face supply constraints as they depend on imports of inputs of production. This leads to a regressive distribution of income, which contributes to the growing distributive conflict and fuels inflation further, as workers oppose to the lowering of real wages. Moreover, the currency rationing puts pressure on the black market for exchange as the devaluation expectations increase, leading to a parallel market devaluation-inflation spiral, which threatens to turn into hyperinflation. Nevertheless, we argue that hyperinflation, according to the proposed post-Keynesian framework (the flight to foreign currency), does not materialise despite skyrocketing prices because of the particular institutional setting – the exchange controls, which have been in place since 2003, prevent full currency substitution.

Keywords: hyperinflation, foreign exchange, distributive conflict, expectations, Dutch disease,

Venezuela

JEL Codes: E12, E31, O54

Contact:

Marta Kulesza

Email: [email protected]

Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Jonathan Marie for giving me the idea to work on this topic and for his continuous support throughout the process of writing this paper. I am also grateful to Eckhard Hein for very helpful comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are of course mine.

Page 4: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

1

1.IntroductionIn the present paper we aim to explain the reasons behind the current episode of rapidly

increasing prices in Venezuela and establish whether it can be considered to be of

hyperinflationary nature. The analysis is done within the post-Keynesian framework of

hyperinflation developed by Marie (2014) around the case of Argentinian hyperinflation of

1989. This theoretical framework was chosen because certain commonalities, such as the

importance of primary sector exports, a tendency to currency overvaluation and a negative

experience with IMF reforms, can be found between the two Latin American economies. In

order to determine the nature of accelerating inflation, the recent developments in the

Venezuelan economy, including economic, social and political circumstances, are analysed,

highlighting the role of distributive conflict, balance of payments constraint, expectations and

flight from domestic currency to foreign currency, as proposed in the theoretical framework.

This research is considered important, firstly, because the phenomenon of hyperinflation has

not been studied extensively within the post-Keynesians tradition. Although the episodes of

hyperinflation are rare and short-lived, the mechanism behind their occurrence should be

well-understood because it reveals the nature of money – the existence of a currency is based

on the confidence in it, and because of its considerable consequences for the economy, such

as the loss of sovereign monetary policy or adverse real effects. Secondly, although the

recurring periods of high inflation since the late 1970s in Venezuela have been researched by

some, the current situation, which appears to be of hyperinflationary nature, has not been

studied yet within the post-Keynesian framework. Therefore, in this paper, we try to

contribute to a better understanding of the developments leading to high inflation (and

eventual hyperinflation) in general, and in Venezuela in particular1.

We find that the current high inflationary environment is a result of the balance of payments

problems, which can predominantly be explained by the years of real exchange rate

overvaluation (the Dutch disease) and low private investment, as they led to a tightening of

the balance of payments constraint. In the face of growing external constraint, foreign

currency rationing was introduced, leading to shortages, output contraction and growing

pressure on the parallel exchange market. As a result, the devaluation expectations

augmented, causing the parallel market devaluation-inflation spiral, which threatens to turn

into hyperinflation as the loss of confidence in the national currency is observed.

1 In case of Venezuela we argue that hyperinflation, according to the proposed post-Keynesian framework does not materialise despite skyrocketing prices because the exchange controls prevent full currency substitution.

Page 5: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

2

The paper is structured as follows: section 2 provides the definition of hyperinflation in the

post-Keynesian tradition and presents the theoretical framework, which is applied in the

empirical part. In section 3, we analyse the macroeconomic trajectory of the Venezuelan

economy since the 1970s and focus in greater detail on the developments since 1999 until the

beginning of 2017. Section 4 provides an assessment of our case study against the proposed

theoretical framework and section 5 concludes.

2.Theoreticalframework:post-KeynesiantheoryofhyperinflationThe phenomenon of hyperinflation in the orthodox literature is defined as a period of very

rapid inflation. Although the threshold is arbitrary, the most common criterion used by

mainstream economists refers to the value proposed by Cagan (1956), where he defines

hyperinflation as a monthly inflation exceeding 50 percent. The definition of hyperinflation in

the post-Keynesian perspective, on the other hand, focuses on its qualitative characteristics

and not merely on the quantitative criteria proposed by the orthodox school.

The seminal work on hyperinflation in the post-Keynesian tradition for a closed economy was

done by Kalecki (1962, p. 275), where he defined hyperinflation as “a very rapid rise in prices

and a general tendency to convert money into goods”. In this framework, the role of inflation

expectations plays a crucial role as the hoarding of goods and the flight from money is

explained by the anticipation of continuous and rapid increases in prices. In turn, the velocity

of money depends on the anticipated rate of inflation, which is based on the past inflation

rates. Thus, as agents expect inflation to accelerate, they will try to dispose of their money,

which accelerates the speed of circulation of money and triggers galloping inflation.

Inspired by Kalecki’s work, Charles and Marie (2016, p.1) provide the following definition of

hyperinflation in an open economy: “a very rapid rise in prices and a general tendency to

convert units of domestic currency into foreign currency”. It is crucial to understand that the

phenomenon of hyperinflation in the adopted post-Keynesian framework does not mean high

or very high inflation, but is rather associated with another important indicator: the loss of the

central bank’s ability to conduct monetary policy. Thus, the crucial criterion used to

determine whether hyperinflation takes place is the gradual rejection of national currency and

the dollarisation of the economy, where another country’s currency is used in exchange for or

in addition to the national currency.2 The reason behind the substitution of national currency

2 On the other hand, not all dollarised economies struggle with hyperinflation.

Page 6: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

3

with foreign currency in the high inflation environment can be explained by liquidity

preference, which is a preference for holding highly liquid assets whose values are stable

(Charles and Marie, 2016). If the domestic currency’s value is not stable as a result of high

domestic inflation or depreciation, foreign currency can better meet the liquidity preference.

The process of currency substitution first begins when savings start being held in a foreign

currency. Subsequently, the use of the dollar (or another foreign currency) as a unit of account

is observed, which is followed by an increased tendency to make payments in a foreign

currency. The loss of confidence in the national currency and its rejection can be observed

quantitatively in the fall of the real value of the monetary base, as the ratio M/P falls (M refers

to monetary base and P to the level of prices), which according to Orléan (2007) is an

important characteristic of every hyperinflationary episode. During hyperinflation, as the

prices increase faster than the money supply, the real value of the total currency in circulation

desired by the economic actors falls, revealing the loss of confidence in the national currency.

In addition to divergent definitions of hyperinflation, post-Keynesian authors propose a

theoretical framework which explains the mechanism behind the emergence of hyperinflation.

According to the orthodox theory, hyperinflation, like inflation, is an excess demand

phenomenon caused by the excessive money supply, which is exogenously controlled by the

central bank (Cagan, 1956). This view corresponds to the quantity theory of money and it

maintains that the excess money supply is a result of government’s irresponsible fiscal

policies (government issues large amounts of money to pay for its fiscal expenditure, which in

turn causes inflation). This view is opposed by post-Keynesians, who believe that money is

endogenous and thus reject the idea that inflation is caused by the excess supply of money

(Lavoie, 2014, Chapter 8). Instead, as we explain below, in the post-Keynesian framework,

inflation is a result of a conflict over the distribution of income.

2.1TheroleofdistributiveconflictBefore discussing the role of distributive conflict in the inflation generating process, pricing

theory has to be briefly explained. While neoclassical pricing theory is based on the equality

of marginal cost and marginal revenue and the notion that firms are price takers, post-

Keynesians argue that firms are in fact price makers in that they set prices based on their

costs, to which they add a mark-up (Lavoie, 2014, Chapter 3). Since the wage bill forms the

biggest part of capitalists’ costs, the variation in wages will have an important impact on price

changes. However, this does not imply that wages by themselves determine prices. It is a

conflict over distribution of income between labour and non-labour constituents of the firm

Page 7: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

4

that will trigger inflation (Lavoie, 2014, Chapter 8). Inflation will arise when workers increase

nominal wages and firms increase prices in order to achieve their respective target income

shares (Blecker, 2011).

The rate of inflation will then depend on the relative bargaining power of labour and the

market power of firms and the discrepancy between their respective wage targets, known as

the “aspiration gap” (Lavoie, 2014, p.549). Workers’ ability to increase their wages will be

positively correlated with their bargaining power, which is in turn determined by formal or

informal institutional settings that reduce the conflict over income (Setterfield, 2007),

including the level of unemployment (Rowthorn, 1977), and presence and strength of trade

unions (Susjan and Lah, 1997). If workers’ bargaining power increases, they will increase

their wage targets, which impacts the “aspiration gap”. Firms’ market power, on the other

hand, and thus their ability to lower their wage targets (or increase mark-up targets), is

influenced by the presence of oligopolistic markets, changes in overhead costs (mark-up being

elastic to different overhead costs, including gross profit claims), and the rate of capacity

utilisation (if capital utilisation is low, firms tend to increase output if effective demand

increases, not prices). Another important cost that can affect firms’ mark-up is the financial

cost or the interest rate. If the interest rate increases, firms may try to pass on the higher cost

of financing their borrowing by increasing their prices (Charles and Marie, 2017). Apart from

bargaining powers, wage and price setting behaviour of workers and firms will also be

impacted by the changes in exchange rates. The phenomenon of exchange rate pass-through

measures the effect of changes in exchange rate on import prices and hence domestic inflation

(Lavoie, 2014, Chapter 7). Depreciation of domestic currency will usually lead to a higher

cost of imported consumer goods, which reduces workers purchasing power, inducing them to

demand higher nominal wages; it also increases the cost of imported materials and semi-

finished products used in domestic production, prompting firms to raise prices, in order to

recover profitability (Blecker, 2011).

2.2IndexationmechanismIf inflation caused by a distributive conflict is high and volatile, agents will develop wage

indexation mechanisms in order to protect their real incomes (Frenkel, 1979). The role of

indexation as an inflation propagation mechanism was pointed out by many neo-structuralists

who studied institutional mechanisms that maintained high inflation rates in Latin America in

the 1970s/80s (Câmara, and Vernengo, 2001). As argued, for example, by Carvalho (1993),

indexation practices not only maintain the current level of inflation, but can also contribute to

Page 8: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

5

its acceleration. If expectations regarding future inflation change because agents anticipate an

acceleration in inflation, the “inflation regime” based on indexation breaks down because the

expectations of rising prices are reflected in the present level of prices. As prices increase, the

current income levels fall below the acceptable level (lags in adjustments cause real incomes

to fall) and agents will react by demanding higher compensation. As a result, the current

system of indexed contracts can become disrupted, leading firms to anticipate increases in

prices and change the way their costs and mark-ups are calculated, thus accelerating the

current inflation further. Thus, an inflation regime characterised by indexation cannot be

sustained because ultimately it does not solve the distributional conflict, but merely

institutionalises it until an external shock hits the economy and breaks down the regime.

Although indexation mechanisms are important propagators of inflation, they may not be a

sufficient condition for the development of hyperinflationary dynamics (Charles and Marie,

2016).

2.3Balanceofpayments,externalindebtednessandexpectationsIn addition to distributive conflict and indexation mechanism, the effect of balance of

payments dynamics, external indebtedness and exchange rate expectations have to be

considered, as these aspects are especially relevant to the emergence of hyperinflation.

According to Câmara and Vernengo (2001), balance of payment problems, which in Latin

America had their source in the structural dependency on capital imports and a shortage of

foreign reserves, led to a depreciation in the domestic currency and hence are an important

part of the inflationary dynamics (the already mentioned exchange rate pass-through

mechanism). Accordingly, any shock to the terms of trade could trigger an inflationary

process, which would then be propagated by distributional conflict and indexation

mechanisms.

Thus, in the structuralist approach, the open economy issues play a central role and inflation is

considered to have its origin in external pressures. Primary-exporting countries tend to

experience “external bottlenecks”, which appear when “a country lacks the foreign exchange

required to maintain its productive capacity fully employed” (Diamand, 1978, p.20). In other

words, the external bottleneck appears when a country, whose productive activity depends on

importing an essential input of production, faces insufficient foreign currency to import such

inputs. In that case, the balance of payments and the supply side can become binding

constraints.

Page 9: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

6

Finally, firms’ expectations regarding the future nominal exchange rate are crucial for the

development of hyperinflation. As mentioned by Frankel (1979), pricing decisions of firms do

not depend only on their costs, but also on the level of uncertainty, information and perceived

future risks. Therefore, if the economy is indebted in a foreign currency and has a current

account deficit, agents can develop anticipations of devaluation (if the exchange rates are

fixed) or depreciation because it would enable the economy to improve its competitiveness

and diminish its trade deficit (Marie, 2014). Such devaluation will have inflationary

consequences because it will raise import prices and the value of external debt, which will in

turn induce firms to increase their prices in order to protect their mark-ups. Thus, firms which

anticipate devaluation can increase their prices today and consequently incite inflation.

Additionally, the anticipation of devaluation can trigger a run on the reserves of foreign

currency where agents try to replace as quickly as possible the domestic currency with a

stable foreign currency (Marie, 2014). As a result, the domestic currency can be rejected in

favour of a foreign currency. This triggers more devaluation followed by reinforced inflation

and the economy enters a vicious circle of inflation and devaluation. The rejection of the use

of domestic currency is the crucial component of the post-Keynesian theoretical approach to

hyperinflation (Marie, 2014).

3.Venezuela–casestudyIn order to understand the most recent developments in the Venezuela (discussed in sections

3.4-3.6), certain structural features of the economy (3.1) as well as the economic and political

events (including the development of the inflation regime) prior to Chavez’s ascendency to

power have to be discussed (3.2 and 3.3).

3.1Theroleofoil,DutchdiseaseandcollapseinprivateinvestmentThe defining feature of the Venezuelan economy is its heavy reliance on oil rents, which has

shaped its economic and social policies and influenced considerably most of the

macroeconomic outcomes in the country during the past decades. The rentier nature of the

Venezuelan economy means that its development and growth came to depend on volatile

economic activity (oil rents), which is subject to external factors that are beyond its control,

making the whole economy vulnerable (Palma, 2011).

The discovery of oil in the early 20th century enabled Venezuela to experience its golden

years between the 1920s and the 1970s (Hausmann and Rodriguez, 2014). However, oil

revenues started to fall in the late 1970s, which reduced considerably the sources of export

Page 10: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

7

and fiscal revenues.3 A reduction in oil production translated into a fall in the share of oil in

GDP, which fell from an average of over 40 percent between 1965 and 1974 to 20 percent

between 1985 and 1994, before increasing again to over 25 percent between 1995 and 2002

(Manzano, 2014). The reduction in the importance of oil was not, however, replaced by other

thriving export industries. The lack of alternative export sectors (non-oil exports accounted

for 7 percent of total exports in 1981) and lack of capacity to develop new export industries in

response to a fall in oil revenues meant that Venezuela was incapable to recover from the

adverse oil shock (Hausmann and Rodriguez, 2014). Thus, following 50 years of rapid

economic expansion, the Venezuelan economy entered a long period of economic decline

with per capita GDP falling by a cumulative 18.6 percent between 1978 and 2001 (Hausmann

and Rodriguez, 2014).

We will argue that the main explanation behind such a dramatic shift in economic

development is the phenomenon of the “resource curse” or “Dutch disease”, which postulates

that abundant natural resources can harm the prospects of economic development. According

to Bresser-Pereira (2012), the Dutch disease is responsible for the chronic overvaluation of

the resource-abundant country’s exchange rate, which prevents structural change (country’s

industrial diversification) or can lead to premature deindustrialisation, harming the prospects

of stable and sustainable economic development. The exchange rate has a tendency to

overvaluation because resource-abundant countries can export their commodities, which are

not reproducible by labour, at a more appreciated exchange rate (“current account equilibrium

level”) compared to the exchange rate that would result from exporting manufactured goods,

which compete in international markets (“industrial equilibrium level”) (Bresser-Pereira et al.,

2014).

It can be observed that since the 1970s, Venezuela has been struggling with many symptoms

of the Dutch disease. The overreliance on oil exports and incapacity to develop other export

sectors and move resources to alternative industries is put forward by Hausmann and

Rodriguez (2014) as one of the main factors explaining the collapse in economic growth

following the late 1970s crisis. Another important factor explaining the dramatic drop in GDP

growth since the 1970s is a large fall in productivity, which occurred in the same period.

Puente et al. (2010) point out that the currency appreciation and protective measures such as

3 The fall in oil revenues was due to both lower prices (since the early 1980s) and declining oil production. According to Manzano (2014), the oil production was reduced as a result of a misguided belief formed in the 1970s that oil reserves were near exhaustion and thus limits on extraction were introduced.

Page 11: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

8

trade barriers, unconditional subsidies, tax exemptions and price controls in certain non-

tradable sectors led to a transfer of resources and labour from tradable and higher productivity

sectors to non-tradable and lower productivity sectors. This in turn contributed to a large fall

in total factor productivity between 1970 and 1983 (it fell by 40 percent) and labour

productivity between 1974 and 1988, which fell by over 30 percent. Such a collapse in

productivity levels had negative long-term effects on the productive capacity of Venezuela

and its long-term growth.

The fall in productivity can also be explained by the collapse of private investment since the

end of the 1970s (Figure 1). According to Gutiérrez and Labarca (2003), over-accumulation

of capital led to declining profitability and thus discouraged investment. While the over-

accumulation argument can have some merit in explaining the very rapid increase in private

investment from the early 1970s and its consequent collapse in the late 1970s, it cannot

explain the very low private investment levels that followed in the 1980s, 1990s and early

2000s. We will argue below that the low level of investment persisted mainly due to the

overvalued real exchange rate – a consequence of the Dutch disease.

Figure 1: Private investment as a share of GDP (%), 1950-2001

Source: Gutiérrez and Labarca (2003, p.7)

Given the importance of imports of intermediate inputs and raw materials for domestic

production in Venezuela (Vera, 2017), a growth constraint based on foreign currency or

external bottlenecks can arise. Consequently, Venezuela’s economic growth could become

limited by the balance of payments (BOP) performance: as the primary sector surplus falls,

the current account deficit emerges, followed by a currency devaluation and usually a deep

Page 12: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

9

recession. According to Thirlwall’s law (Thirlwall, 1979), the maximum growth that the

BOP-constrained countries can attain will positively depend on the income elasticity of

demand for exports by foreign countries and the (exogenous) world demand growth rate, and

negatively on the income elasticity of demand for imports. Bértola and Ocampo’s (2012, p.

29) estimations for Venezuela show that while the income elasticity of demand for exports

was higher than the income elasticity of demand for imports during different periods between

1870 and 1980, the 1980 to 2008 period was characterised by a large increase in the import

elasticity, which meant that the Venezuelan economy became increasingly dependent on

imports.

This dramatic deterioration in elasticities can be explained endogenously by considering the

impact of the real exchange rate. As pointed out by Bresser-Pereira et al. (2014, p.7), chronic

overvaluation of the exchange rate affects the productive structure of the economy by

“inducing a perverse specialisation process in production of goods intense in natural resources

and causing low growth due to de-industrialization”. As we have already mentioned above,

the currency appreciation in Venezuela contributed to the transfer of labour and resources to

low productivity, non-tradable, sectors. In addition, a persistent real appreciation of the

bolivar had a negative effect on private investment, as it reduced the competitiveness of

Venezuelan products and negatively affected the firms’ profit margins. Thus, the currency

overvaluation can partly explain the falling rates of private investment since the 1980s (Figure

1) and premature deindustrialisation since the mid-1980s (Vera, 2011), which in turn

impacted the income elasticities (income elasticity of demand for exports fell, while income

elasticity of demand for imports increased). In this context, the continuous currency

appreciation4 (Figure 2) can explain the observed worsening of income elasticities in

Venezuela since the 1980s.

4 No data was available for the prior 1990 period, however Palma (2008, 2011) reported that since the late 1970s the Venezuelan authorities have been struggling with excessively appreciating domestic currency as the regime of moderate inflation started in the mid-1970s and the exchange rate was kept fixed.

Page 13: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

10

Figure 2: Real exchange rate, 1990-2013, 2005=100

Source: ECLAC (2016)

The chronic currency overvaluation, as defined by Bresser-Pereira et al. (2014), thus

negatively affected the productive structure of the Venezuelan economy and led to the

tightening of the BOP constraint. The loss of competitiveness in non-oil sectors translated into

an increasing dependence on imports, especially of inputs of production, which in turn has

made local production dependent on the economy’s capacity to import, which is constrained

by the availability of international reserves. Thus, the economy’s performance has become

constrained by external bottlenecks, which arise every time export revenues fall or import

costs increase.

3.2Risingcostsofproduction,exchangeratepolicyanddistributiveconflictAfter decades of price stability until the mid-1970s – a sign of Venezuela’s ability to contain

and regulate distributive and social conflict (Di John, 2005), the economy started

experiencing rising rates of inflation (Table 1) following the oil boom of the 1970s.

Table 1: Average inflation rates, 1950-1999

Period Average inflation rate (%)

Standard deviation of average inflation rate

1950-1959 1.3 1.9 1960-1969 1.4 1.1 1970-1979 6 3.2 1980-1989 19.4 16.2 1990-1999 47.4 22

Source: Based on Guerra (2002, p. 16), author’s presentation

020406080

100120140160180

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

Page 14: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

11

The oil shocks of 1973 and 1979 had particular consequences for the Venezuelan economy.

On the one hand, the oil windfall allowed for a rapid demand growth, which, however, had to

be accommodated by an increase in imports given that many sectors in the Venezuelan

economy faced supply constraints (Vera, 2016). On the other hand, higher energy prices

following the oil shocks meant that the prices of most of the Venezuelan suppliers increased

considerably, thus leading to higher costs of imported inputs of production for Venezuelan

firms (Ortiz, 1987). In addition, Venezuelan firms faced higher labour costs following a

number of pro-labour legal reforms that were introduced in 1974, such as the establishment of

national minimum salary and a general increase in wages, up to 25 percent for the lowest

salaries (Portillo, 2004). Moreover, the average nominal wage growth between 1973 and 1980

was well above the growth in labour productivity (Ortiz, 1987), which also contributed to

rising inflation.

Thus, growing costs of production in the form of higher wages and higher input costs since

1974, and since 1979, in combination with the higher costs of financing (following the

restrictive monetary policy), induced firms to raise prices in order to protect their profit

margins. In addition, in August 1979 there was a partial abandonment of price controls

(Portillo, 2004), which also partly contributed to an increase in inflation rates from 9.2 percent

in 1979 to 20.1 percent in 1980. The 1974 pro-labour market policies and very low

unemployment rate (in 1978 it was only 4.3 percent) strengthened the bargaining power of

labour. Thus, when firms increased their prices, workers reacted by demanding higher

nominal wages in order to preserve their purchasing power, which in turn resulted in moderate

inflation rates during the 1970s that were unknown in previous decades (Table 1).

Nevertheless, the increases in inflation rates in the 1970s were minor compared to the

acceleration that took place in the 1980s and 1990s following the changes in exchange rate

policy and resulting distributive conflict. The exhaustion of the accumulation model based on

oil revenues became increasingly evident in the 1980s (Lander, 1996), and had an important

effect on price dynamics. The crisis in Venezuela that broke out in February 1983 was

characterised by declining terms of trade (due to a fall in oil prices) and a massive increase in

capital outflows (a result of growing expectations of devaluation). In addition, the outbreak of

the 1980s Latin American debt crisis contributed to the development of pessimistic

expectations regarding Venezuela’s ability to repay its external debt and forced the

government to devalue the bolivar (for the first time since 1973) and introduce exchange

Page 15: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

12

controls with multiple exchange rates that would remain in place until 1989 (Kelly and Palma,

2004).

Figure 3: Yearly average inflation rates (%), 1980-1998

Source: IMF (2016)

The introduction of exchange controls and devaluation in 1983 had an important impact on

the distributive conflict. On the one hand, it increased the cost of imported materials and

intermediate goods for firms. On the other hand, the cost of imported consumer goods also

increased thus reducing the purchasing power of workers. The fall in firms’ profitability was

not, however, counteracted by an increase in prices (in fact inflation slowed down in 1983 and

increased somewhat in 1984, stabilising thereafter, Figure 3) as firms were able to reduce

workers’ wages in order to preserve their profit margins. The subsequent severe recession and

growing unemployment reduced significantly the bargaining power of labour. As a result, the

wage share in national income fell from 50.2 percent in 1983 to 39.8 percent in 1984 (Figure

4).

Although the economy recovered already in 1984, the 1986 oil price collapse worsened

significantly Venezuela’s external position. The terms of trade dropped considerably, leading

to a large current account balance decline from a surplus of $3.3 billion to a deficit of over $2

billion. The authorities reacted by carrying out almost a 50 percent devaluation in December

of 1986 (Palma, 2011), which led to a renewal of the distributive conflict and an increase in

inflation rates – firms’ market power remained high, as the economy grew at an average rate

of 5.8 percent between 1986-1988, and workers’ could demand higher wages as the

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1980

1981

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Page 16: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

13

unemployment rate was falling since 1985. As a result, the inflation rate increased from 11.5

percent in 1986 to almost 30 percent in 1988 (Figure 3).

Figure 4: Percentage share of wages in GDP (%), 1982-1992

Source: Based on Lander (2006, p. 135), author’s presentation

3.3Theneoliberaladjustment,bankingcrisisandchangesinexchangeratepolicyWhile Venezuela was able to avoid the IMF intervention during the 1983 crisis, the growing

macroeconomic disequilibria in the late 1980s, prioritisation of external debt repayment5 and

growing private capital flight forced the country to finally make an adjustment in 1989

(Lander, 1996).The IMF adjustment programme in Venezuela was similar to those adopted in

other Latin American countries as it aimed to re-establish macroeconomic equilibria by

restricting public expenditure, eliminating price controls, liberalising trade and introducing a

single floating exchange rate (Lander, 1996). As a result, in March 1989 the exchange

controls were abolished and a unique floating rate equal to the free market rate of 40 bolivars

(Bs) per US dollar was introduced, which implied another large devaluation (previously

controlled rates were equal to 14.5 and 7.5 Bs/$) (Palma, 2008). Such a large exchange rate

adjustment, combined with the elimination of subsidies and price controls, increases in prices

of public services and goods, rises in nominal wages and growing costs of investment

financing as the interest rates increased, had a significant impact on prices, with the inflation

rate rising to 84 percent in 1989 (Palma, 2008).

5 Unlike many Latin American countries, Venezuela did not default on its external debt during the 1980s debt crisis.

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

Page 17: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

14

The results of the adjustment were disastrous and led to a reduction in real wages (the wage

share in total income fell from 41.4 per cent in 1988 to 33.4 per cent in 1990), higher income

concentration (the Gini coefficient increased from 0.45 in 1989 to 0.48 in 1995), dramatic fall

in private investment (Figure 1) and deterioration in living conditions. In addition, instead of

reducing oil dependency, Venezuela saw the oil’s share of total exports increase further

(Lander, 1996). In this context, Vera (2009) points out that starting in the late 1980s the

Venezuelan economy, traditionally heavily protected and regulated, has been experiencing

premature deindustrialisation following the orthodox macroeconomic adjustment and markets

liberalisation of 1989 (manufacturing employment and the share of manufacturing in GDP

reached their peaks in 1988 and have been falling ever since). Although the GDP growth

recovered between 1990 and 1992, the political unrest, including two unsuccessful coup

attempts in 1992 and the impeachment of president Pérez in 1993, prevented stabilisation and

weakened further the Venezuelan economy (Kelly and Palma, 2004).

The deterioration in the political system and the deepening political crisis, coupled with low

oil prices, led to more economic problems under president Caldera, who took office in 1994.

Just as the new government came to power, a financial crisis erupted in January 1994 with the

bankruptcy of one of the largest banks, the Banco Latino (Kelly and Palma, 2004). With many

financial institutions affected, there was large capital flight despite the central bank

implementing very restrictive monetary policy. This situation forced the authorities to

introduce new exchange controls with a unique fixed exchange rate in July 1994 (Palma,

2011). The severe foreign exchange restrictions (foreign exchange transactions outside the

official market were illegalised) and high interest rates had a negative impact on investment

and production, leading to shortages, which contributed to rapidly accelerating prices.

Moreover, since the end of 1995, the pressures from the depreciating black market rate led to

the formation of expectations of devaluation in the official exchange rate with firms

increasing prices as they expected their future replacement costs to rise (Palma, 2008).

Thus, in the face of growing real exchange rate overvaluation (Figure 2), the authorities

decided to adjust the fixed exchange rate in December 1995 by devaluing the currency from

170 Bs/$ to 290 Bs/$, which led to an increase in the annualised inflation rate from 72 percent

in October 1995 to 150 percent in January 1996 (Palma, 2008). A further large devaluation

was carried out in April 1996 before the exchange rate controls were scraped in July and

replaced by a crawling band system.

Page 18: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

15

Table 2: Exchange rate systems in Venezuela, 1964-2017

Period Exchange rate system Capital controls

1964 – 1983 Fixed exchange rate, free convertibility

1983 – 1989 Exchange controls with multiple exchange rates X

1989 – 1994 Floating exchange rate (1992-1994, unofficial

crawling peg), free convertibility

1994 – 1996 Exchange controls with single fixed exchange rate X

1996 – 2002 Crawling band, free convertibility

2002 – 2003 Floating exchange rate, free convertibility

2003 - present Exchange controls with multiple exchange rates X

Source: Based on Palma (2008), author’s presentation

The overall effects of the liberalisation period in Venezuela left labour’s bargaining power

considerably weakened. The rate of unionisation fell from 26.4 percent of the workforce in

1988 to only 13.5 percent in 1995, while the rate of informality increased from the average of

39.5 percent of the non-agricultural labour force in 1980-1990 to the average of 48.5 percent

in the 1994-1995 period (Di John, 2005). According to Di John (2005, p.9), the fragmentation

of Venezuelan politics and growing informalisation of employment contributed to “de-

institutionalisation of conflict mediation capacity in the Venezuelan polity” because it

weakened the social bases of support for the political parties.

3.4Fromthepoliticalunrestandeconomiccollapsetotemporaryeconomicboom(1999-2008)Following two decades of erratic economic policies, which failed to address the structural

problems of the economy and merely postponed the dramatic adjustments that contributed to

declining living standards, growing inequality and poverty, corruption and a deteriorating

political system, it does not come as a surprise that Venezuelans were looking for a change in

how their country was managed. According to Lampa (2016), the rise of Chavism can be

partly explained by the negative and violent social reactions to Pérez’s neoliberal adjustments.

After a campaign full of anti-political and anti-neoliberal rhetoric, Hugo Chávez was elected

president at the end of 1998 and took office in 1999.

The new administration continued the exchange policy of the crawling band, which had been

in place since 1996, with an aim of using the exchange rate as a nominal anchor to keep the

inflation under control (Palma, 2008). The policy was successful in bringing down the

inflation rate, which fell from 23.6 percent in 1999 to 12.5 in 2001 (Table 3). However, the

Page 19: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

16

global recession that started in September 2001, as well as an increase in the oil production by

the non-OPEC countries meant that the price of oil started falling again at the beginning of

2002. At the same time, the growing political uncertainty in Venezuela (discussed below)

caused an increase in the demand for dollars as agents started buying foreign currency as a

protection mechanism in case of a looming economic and political crisis (Palma, 2008). The

Central Bank of Venezuela (Banco Central de Venezuela, BCV) responded to the speculative

currency attack by selling dollars to satisfy the demand and by implementing a restrictive

monetary policy (the lending rate increased from 21.1 percent in February 2001 to 53.6

percent in February 2002). However, the situation became unsustainable as the central bank’s

international reserves contracted rapidly (they fell from $21.2 billion in January 2001 to $16.7

billion in January 2002) and the defence of the crawling band system had to be abandoned. It

was replaced in February 2002 by the single floating exchange rate with free convertibility.

The first few years of Chávez’s presidency were marked by a rise in political turmoil,

institutional uncertainty and capital flight (Vera, 2015). The adoption of new constitution in

1999, strengthening presidential powers and promoting transformative economic policies, was

met with vehement opposition from business elites, but also from trade unions, which were

closely linked with the old political regime and the AD (Acción Democrática) party, now in

opposition. The antagonism to the proposed radical transformation of the Venezuelan

economy led to a general strike in December 2001, which culminated in a failed coup attempt

in April 2002 (Lampa, 2016). Another wave of strikes between late 2002 and early 2003

paralysed oil production for a few months, which had catastrophic consequences for the

economy. The GDP fell by 25 percent in the first trimester of 2003 with many businesses

going bankrupt (also a result of the very restrictive monetary policy since 2002) and the

situation of labour worsening further (the unemployment reached over 18 percent and the rate

of informal employment increased to 55 percent) (Kelly and Palma, 2004). The adverse

economic and political circumstances led to a massive capital flight, bringing about a large

depreciation (the value of bolivar fell by 47 percent between December 2002 and January

2003) and a decline in international reserves (Kelly and Palma, 2004). As a result, foreign

exchange controls were established followed by price controls for basic consumption goods,

which set some of the prices at below cost levels, forcing certain producers out of business

and reducing market power of the affected firms.6

6 According to the Gaceta Oficial Nº 37.626 , a decree introducing price controls affected the producers of 45 basic necessity goods (mainly foodstuff) and providers of 7 services.

Page 20: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

17

The foreign exchange controls with a single official fixed exchange rate were implemented in

February 2003 and a Commission for Foreign Currency Administration (Comisión de

Administración de Divisas or CADIVI) was established to manage it. All foreign currency

earned from exports or from any other source, such as tourism or remittances, had to be sold

to the central bank at the official exchange rate, while obtaining the foreign currency at the

official exchange rate for imports or servicing of private debt was limited and subject to

approval by the commission (Palma, 2008). In addition, a parallel market was created in order

to satisfy growing demand for foreign currency where the exchange rate was determined by

the law of supply and demand. The foreign currency could be obtained in this parallel market

by exchanging bolivar-denominated securities for dollar-denominated bonds, which were later

sold in the international markets (Palma, 2016). The parallel market remained an important

source of legally available foreign currency until it was illegalised in 2010.

The uncertainty, political instability of 2002 and 2003, along with the introduction of

exchange and price controls seem to have negatively affected the market power of firms. The

restricted allocation of dollars meant that many importers and firms that relied on imports of

materials and capital for their production had to use the parallel market to obtain the foreign

currency, which implied an important increase in their costs. The retailers’ profit margins

suffered considerably due to a fall in sales and price controls, as they were not able pass over

onto consumers the higher costs that they had to pay to their suppliers (the wholesale price

index was rising faster than the consumer price index (Palma, 2008). Workers’ bargaining

power, already weakened following the neoliberal adjustments in the previous decade, was

also negatively affected by high rates of unemployment (it increased from 13.4 percent in

2001 to 18.2 percent in 2003), which translated into a fall in real wages as the increases in

nominal wages that workers were able to negotiate were far below the average consumer

inflation rates in 2002 and 2003.

Table 3: Nominal wage growth and inflation (%), 1999-2008

1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Public sector 14.8 31.8 36.9 5.1 5.3 37.7 26.6 29.6 23.4 27.6

Private sector 28.7 18.0 15.2 9.6 9.6 17.0 16.2 15.1 19.4 23.7

General 25.5 20.9 20.2 8.4 8.5 22.0 19.1 19.3 20.7 25.0 CPI (average prices) 23.6 16.2 12.5 22.4 31.1 21.7 16.0 13.7 18.7 30.4

Note: CPI refers to consumer price index

Source: Venezuelan Central Bank (2015) and IMF (2016)

Page 21: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

18

Thus, the currency depreciation in 2002 and an increase in the cost of imported goods

following the introduction of exchange controls as well as high costs of financing (restrictive

monetary policy was introduced in 2002) jeopardised the distributional arrangement that

existed between profits and wages. This led to a fall in real wages and the wage share (it

decreased from 38.2 in 2001 to 33.3 in 2003), and contributed to accelerating inflation, which

reached 31.1 percent in 2003, as compared to 12.5 percent in 2001.

According to Vera (2015), following the political turmoil of 2002-2003, the commodity boom

and increasing state control of the oil rent enabled Chávez’s government to pursue an

economic regime based on the prominent role of the state in the economy. The regime was

characterised by going beyond market mechanisms in their regulation of production and

distribution of certain goods and services, which included the adoption of alternative

ownership structures and control over the means of production as well as the expropriation of

strategically important industries. In addition, more discretionary powers replaced the

traditional institutions governing oil revenues, which allowed for a large expansion of

domestic demand. The demand-oriented strategy pursued by the government was based on

two pillars: an increase in fiscal spending on social programmes and a real exchange rate

appreciation. The social spending as a share of GDP (including the spending by the state-

owned oil company PDVSA7) increased from 8.2 percent in 1998 to 20.9 in 2006 (Weisbrot

and Sandoval, 2007). As for the second pillar, Lampa (2016) points out that the strategy of

keeping the currency appreciated and thus making the imports cheaper was a necessary

condition for the implementation of the demand-led economic growth given the structure of

consumption in Venezuela, which largely depends on imports. The combination of an

expansion in aggregate demand and a real exchange rate appreciation (Figure 2) led to a

massive increase in the volume of imports, from $8.3 billion in 2003 to $45.1 billion in 2008.

Allowing imports to grow so dramatically required careful consideration of external and

internal balances as well as sizeable stock of international reserves in case of a decline in oil

revenues (Lampa, 2016). The Venezuelan government managed to achieve all these

objectives between 2004 and 2008 by running a large current account surplus, reducing its

public debt and increasing its stock of foreign reserves.

The combination of a spectacular rise in oil prices and large fiscal spending funded by oil

windfalls resulted in an impressive 5-year average (2004-2008) real GDP growth of 10.5

7 PDVSA’s (Petróleos de Venezuela) social spending in 2006 amounted to 7.3 percent of the GDP (Weisbrot and Sandoval, 2007).

Page 22: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

19

percent. Consequently, the unemployment rate fell from 18.2 percent (2003) to 7.4 percent

(2008). Social and inequality indicators also improved: the poverty rate fell to 27.5 percent

compared with 55.1 percent in 2003, while the Gini coefficient decreased from 0.48 (2003) to

0.41 (2008). Moreover, the inflation rate declined considerably between 2003 and 20078 even

though real wages grew in this period (Table 3), which suggests that the aspiration gap

between workers and firms diminished as firms accepted lower mark-ups during the economic

boom years (assuming that the productivity growth was lower than the real wage growth).

However, such economic expansion could only last as long as oil prices remained elevated.

Lack of industrial policies9 that would diversify local productive capacity and continued weak

private investment (according to World Bank data, the share of private sector gross fixed

capital formation in GDP was only 9.8 percent in 2008) contributed to a further increase in oil

dependency. In this context, domestic growth was increasingly constrained by world demand

for oil. Thus, when the global financial and economic crisis started in the second half of 2008,

leading to a fall in demand and oil prices, the Venezuelan economy was severely impacted

and all policy efforts had to be redirected to deal with the threat of external and fiscal crises

(Vera, 2015).

3.5Economicroller-coaster(2009-2012)

3.5.1ExternalconstraintandexchangerateadjustmentsAs the oil prices plummeted, falling from $129 per barrel in July 2008 to only $31 per barrel

in December 2008 (Palma, 2008), Venezuela’s GDP contracted, driven primarily by the

reduction in exports and investment (Table 4). In addition, the government slowed down its

fiscal expenditure, which had increased only by 1.5 percent, in order to maintain fiscal

balance as the oil revenues fell by almost 40 percent in 2009 (Vera, 2015) and the current

account surplus almost disappeared, falling from 10.8 percent of GDP in 2008 to only 0.2

percent in 2009.

8 The inflation rate increased in 2008 to 30.4 percent due to partial price liberalisation at the end of 2007 (Palma, 2011). 9 According to Vera (2011), Chávez’s administration left the industrial policies in limbo and did not undertake any important initiatives to reverse the process of premature deindustrialisation that has been taking place in Venezuela since the late 1980s. In fact, between 1999 and 2007 the growth of manufacturing GDP was the worst during the last 40 years (Vera, 2009).

Page 23: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

20

Table 4: Rate of growth of GDP and demand components, 2007-2014

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 GDP growth rate (%) 8.75 5.28 -3.20 -1.49 4.18 5.63 1.34 -3.89 Growth rate (%):

Consumption 16.89 6.32 -2.92 -1.87 4.02 7.02 4.72 -3.36 Gov. Expenditure 13.75 4.78 1.54 2.14 5.92 6.26 3.34 0.64

Investment 28.16 2.19 -19.08 1.04 15.19 24.06 -13.95 -

22.92 Exports -7.55 -0.98 -13.68 -12.88 4.66 1.59 -6.17 -4.66

Imports 33.01 1.36 -19.56 -2.89 15.39 24.40 -9.69 -

18.53

Source: Venezuelan Central Bank (2015), author’s calculations

In the face of the economic crisis, the central bank adjusted the interest rates downwards and

prompted credit allocation for manufacturing in order to stimulate economic activity. On the

other hand, instead of allowing the currency to float and absorb the economic shock, the

Venezuelan authorities decided to reduce the allocation of foreign exchange for import

payments in order to maintain the fixed parity (Vera, 2015). This led to a significant decrease

in imports (-19.6 percent) and had a negative impact on the local production, which is heavily

dependent on imports of intermediate inputs and capital goods. As a result, the economic

activity slowed down, despite expansive monetary policy, contributing to a reduction in the

inflation rate (from 31 percent in 2008 to 25 percent in 2009).

Despite some recovery in oil prices in 2010, the recession persisted mainly because of the

continued fall in exports (due to low world demand) and domestic consumption, as well as

due to the lack of expansive fiscal policy (Table 4). The considerable loss of foreign reserves

and a significant drop in the terms of trade in 2009 forced the authorities to finally adjust the

exchange rate in January 2010 (for the first time since 2005) by introducing a two-tier

exchange rate system. The exchange rate of 2.6 BsF (bolivar fuerte10) per US dollar devalued

from 2.15 BsF/$ and was reserved for the imports of selected products, such as food, drugs,

machinery and equipment, while the new rate of 4.3 BsF/$ was to be used for other imports.

In addition, in June 2010, the authorities introduced another type of exchange rate equal to 5.3

BsF/$ reserved for non-urgent imports, which had to be authorised by the newly created

commission called SITME (Sistema de Transacciones con Títulos en Moneda Extranjera)

(Lampa, 2016). SITME effectively replaced the parallel market, which became illegal in May

10 The bolivar (Bs) was revalued in January 2008 and it was renamed the bolivar fuerte (BsF). The revaluation was the at the ratio of 1 to 1000 so that 1000 bolivar became equal 1 bolivar fuerte and the dollar exchange rate changed from 2,150 Bs/$ to 2.15BsF/$.

Page 24: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

21

2010. While it operated by exchanging securities and thus was similar to the parallel market,

the rate at which the exchange could take place was fixed and access to the system was

restricted (Palma, 2016).

In January 2011, the official exchange rate (CENCOEX) was effectively devaluated when the

dual exchange system was eliminated and the official exchange rate became unified to 4.3

BsF/$. At the same time, the SITME exchange rate (5.3 BsF/$) was maintained. The economy

recovered (GDP growth was 4.2 percent in 2011 and 5.6 percent in 2012), however, it was

mainly due to the improvement in oil prices and not to the devaluation strategy (Lampa,

2016). The increase in the value of oil exports allowed the government to increase its

spending, and at the same time the investment saw a significant upturn growing 15 and 24

percent in 2011 and 2012 respectively with imports growing at the exact same pace as

investment (Table 4).

According to Vera (2015), the political cycle played a key role in the economic recovery

during 2011 and 2012, as Chávez was preparing to run for the third term in office. The

devaluation enabled the government to lessen the fiscal gap since it was now receiving more

local currency for the same amount of dollars it earned in exports (Vera, 2015). This allowed

for an increase in total public spending as percentage of GDP from 22.9 percent in 2010 to

26.4 and 28.4 percent in 2011 and 2012 respectively (Vera, 2015). Massive fiscal expansion,

which focused on spending on housing infrastructure and a number of social programmes

directed at Chávez’s core electoral base, comprised mainly of low-income households,

consolidated the economic growth and enabled Chávez to win the elections.

3.5.2GrowingdistributiveconflictIn the second half of 2012, the external constraint became apparent again as the current

account surplus fell to 0.8 percent of GDP and a drastic rationing of foreign exchange

allocations to the private sector had started (Vera, 2015). While between 2010 and 2012 the

inflation rate was higher than the depreciation rate in the parallel exchange market, by the end

of 2012, the sharp increase in the rate of depreciation, driven by the decrease in the allocation

of foreign exchange, capital flight and expectations of devaluation in the official exchange

rate, seem to have been the main driver behind the acceleration in inflation rates.

Page 25: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

22

Table 5: Nominal wage growth, exchange rate devaluation and inflation (%), 2010-2016

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

Public Sector 14.3 39.7 30.0 36.4 NA NA NA

Private Sector 26.0 27.8 27.1 30.6 NA NA NA Parallel exchange rate 5.7 2.8 99.0 299.3 153.6 393.9 293.9

CPI (end of period) 27.2 27.6 20.1 56.2 68.5 180.9 720.011

Source: Venezuelan Central Bank (2015), IMF (2016) and Dollar Today (2017), author’s calculations

Figure 5: Nominal exchange rates and inflation, 2010-2014

Note: CPI refers to consumer price index, CENCOEX (Centro Nacional de Comercio Exterior or the National Center for Foreign Commerce) refers to the official exchange rate administered by that government body.

Source: Venezuelan Central Bank (2015) and Dollar Today (2017)

Thus, the inflationary dynamics between 2010 and 2012 appear to have been driven by the

distributive conflict outlined in section 2.1. The growing distributive conflict can be observed

in the increase in labour disputes between 2008 and 2011, which more than quadrupled in that

period from 400 to 1800 per year (The Economist, 2014). Following the dramatic real wage

decreases during the 2002-2003 crisis, workers’ bargaining power seems to have been

growing since 2005, as the wage share was increasing (Figure 6).

11 No inflation statistics has been published by the BCV since the end of 2015. The inflation rate for 2016 is according to the IMF estimates.

0.0100.0200.0300.0400.0500.0600.0700.0800.0900.0

020406080

100120140160180200

06-2010

09-2010

12-2010

03-2011

06-2011

09-2011

12-2011

03-2012

06-2012

09-2012

12-2012

03-2013

06-2013

09-2013

12-2013

03-2014

06-2014

09-2014

12-2014

ParallelDollar CENCOEX CPI(2007=100)right-handscale

Page 26: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

23

The relatively low unemployment since 2010 (it fell from 8.5 percent in 2010 to 6.7 percent in

2014) and falling rates of informal sector employment strengthened the bargaining power of

workers who were able to increase their wage share from 32.4 percent in 2010 to 39.1 percent

in 2014 (Figure 6). The increase in the workers’ wage targets can also be explained by the

increase in social spending as a share of public spending, which increased from 58.4 percent

in 2005 to 70.8 percent in 2012, driven almost uniquely by the increase in spending on the

social security (ECLAC, 2016). Higher unemployment benefits strengthened the bargaining

power of labour and hence the workers were able to demand higher wages.

Figure 6: Percentage share of wages in GDP at factor costs (%), 1997-2014

Source : ECLAC (2016), and Venezuelan Central Bank (2015), author’s calculations

At the same time, the output gap12 decreased dramatically since 2003 and even turned positive

during 2008-2009 and then 2012-2014 (Figure 7), which implies very high rates of capacity

utilisation and hence higher market power of firms, which could charge higher prices.

Moreover, the official exchange rate devaluations in 2010 and 2011 and the illegalisation of

parallel exchange markets raised the cost of imported materials and intermediate goods used

in production which had a negative impact on firms’ profitability. It can be argued that

following the increase in costs of production, firms attempted to increase their mark-ups over

wages, and thus reduced the real wages by increasing prices in order to recover profitability,

12 The output gap measures the discrepancy between what is produced and an estimate of the output that could be produced without generating demand pressures on inflation. The concept of the output gap is based on the assumption of the existence of NAIRU (non-accelerating inflation rate unemployment) which states that whenever unemployment is below this unique rate, wage and price inflation will accelerate. However the NAIRU concept is rejected by the post-Keynesians (Lavoie, 2014, Chapter 8). Nonetheless, for the lack of data on capacity utilisation, here the output gap is used as an approximation for the rate of capacity utilisation.

20

25

30

35

40

45

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

Page 27: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

24

which led to an increase in the aspiration gap between workers and firms and contributed to

higher inflation rates. Thus, increasing bargaining power of both firms and workers seem to

explain high rates of inflation that persisted between 2010 and 2012 despite the less restrictive

access to foreign currency and growing imports in that period (Table 4).

Figure 7: Output gap (%), 1997-2016

Source: DataStream (2017)

3.6Towardstransitiontohyperinflation?(2013-present)Venezuela has been struggling with double-digit inflation since the end of the 1970s, however

the inflationary dynamic has been markedly accelerating since 2013. Driven primarily by the

growing devaluation expectations, as the external constraint has been worsening since the end

of 2012, it has increased the gap between the parallel and the official exchange rates and led

to an acceleration in inflation rates. As can be seen in Table 6, the worsening of the external

position, especially since 2015, is mainly due to a more than 50 percent fall in oil prices in

that same year and continued low oil prices in 2016.

In addition to low oil prices, some authors point out the negative effect of capital flight on the

price dynamics. According to Lampa (2016), one of the primary reasons behind growing rates

of inflation has been an unprecedented capital flight since the government loosened controls

on capital and increased regulation of the currency market in 2012 in advance of the

upcoming elections. Since growing capital flight reflects expectations of higher inflation and

higher black market dollar rates in the future, the depreciation of the parallel rate could have

-40

-35

-30

-25

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

Page 28: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

25

been driven by the expectations of a reduction in foreign currency rationing, and hence

imports, following the 2012 elections. It is possible that firms realised that the 24 percent

increase in imports in 2012 was unsustainable and thus began to hoard dollars and/or convey

capital abroad in anticipation of a devaluation and reduction in foreign currency provisions.

Table 6: Macroeconomic indicators, 2010-2016

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

Average Oil Price (US$/bl) 71.4 98.2 103.4 99.5 93.7 44.7 35.1

Current Account Balance (Millions of US$)

5,585 16,342 2,586 4,604 3,598 -20,360 -11,205

Current Account Balance (% of GDP)

1.9 4.9 0.8 2.0 1.7 -7.8 -3.4

Net Financial Transfers (Millions of US$) -19,853 -29,453 -14,681 -17,901 -12,691 8,834 NA

Terms of Trade (2000=100) 216 260 262 257 216 125 NA

Inflation, end of period consumer prices (%)

27.2 27.6 20.1 56.2 68.5 180.9 720

Source: Ministry of Energy and Petroleum (2017), IMF (2016), ECLAC (2016) and UNCTAD (2016)

Although it seems that capital flight slowed down since 2011 (Table 6), this statistic does not

account for the illegal capital flight, which in case of Venezuela is known to be one of the

highest in the world. The former president of the Venezuelan Central Bank admitted that in

2012 almost one third of the $59 billion authorised by CADIVI for imports, which was

necessary for productive activities, were in fact embezzled by fake companies (Aporrea,

2013) and that Venezuelan firms systematically over-invoiced their dollar-valued contract

(Lampa, 2016).

Therefore, since the end of 2012 the growing devaluation expectations led to a rapid increase

in the black market value of dollar, which in turn fuelled inflation (Figure 5) as the firms,

expecting devaluation, began to set their prices as if the domestic currency was weaker than

the official exchange rate and thus increased their prices. Moreover, in light of expected

devaluation, commodity hoarding became a common tactic and dollar hoarding became a

more profitable form of saving when compared to the nominal funds rate which was kept very

low despite high inflation rates (Lampa, 2016).

The growing gap between the black market exchange rate and the official exchange rate

eventually induced the authorities to devaluate the bolivar in February 2013. The value of the

nominal exchange rate fell by almost 50 percent (from 4.3 to 6.3 BsF/$), while the SITME

Page 29: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

26

exchange rate was eliminated and replaced by an auction-based SICAD (Sistema

Complementario para la Adquisición de Divisas). Following the devaluation, the amount of

authorised foreign currency for imports was reduced as it became more expensive. Given

Venezuela’s dependency on imports for inputs of production (according to BCV (2013), the

share of capital goods and intermediate products in total imports was 84 percent in 2012), a

decrease in imports following inadequate supply of foreign exchange increased the costs of

production, which in turn was passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices (inflation

increased from 20.1 percent to 56.2 percent between 2012 and 2013). In 2014, the supply of

foreign exchange continued to be inadequate, resulting in a large fall in imports (-18.5 percent

in 2014) which had a negative effect on local production and consumption. As a result, the

GDP contracted by -3.9 percent and inflation reached 68.5 percent in 2014.

As the current account deficit reached 7.8 percent of the GDP in 2015, the government

decided to introduce yet again new types of exchange rates. In 2015, a floating rate SIMADI

(Sistema Marginal de Divisas) was introduced where the exchange rate was supposed to float

according to the supply and demand; its initial value was equal to 170 BsF/$, which at the

time was almost the same as the black market rate. As the external situation did not improve

in 2016, and the gap between the parallel dollar rate and the official rate (CENCOEX)

increased to over 10,000 percent (Figure 8), the authorities changed again their exchange rate

system. The official exchange rate used for importing priority products CENCOEX was

replaced by a new exchange rate DIPRO (Sistema de Divisas Protegidas), also to be used only

for priority imports, and whose value was set at 10 BsF/$. At the same time, the SIMADI was

replaced by the DICOM (Sistema de Divisas Complementarias), which is a controlled floating

exchange rate to be used only for certain foreign currency needs, such as foreign travels,

credit card payments and exchanging dollars obtained from exports to bolivars.

Page 30: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

27

Figure 8: Nominal exchange rates, 2015-2017

Note: SIMADI (Sistema Marginal de Divisas), DICOM (Sistema de Divisas Complementarias - complementary exchange rate), CENCOEX (Centro Nacional de Comercio Exterior or the National Center for Foreign Commerce), DIPRO (Sistema de Divisas Protegidas – protected exchange rate)

Source: Venezuelan Central Bank (2017) and Dollar Today (2017)

Thus, over the last few years, the government’s strategy to correct the growing external

imbalance has been severe foreign exchange rationing, which has generated significant

shortages in intermediate inputs and consumer goods thus contributing to the output

contraction and to accelerating inflation (Vera, 2016). Moreover, the currency rationing has

been putting increasing pressure on the parallel exchange rate market (Figure 8), whose

“exponential” behaviour during the last few months of 2016 and the beginning of 2017 can

suggest that further official exchange rate devaluations are expected.

At the same time, Venezuela’s international reserves have been declining since 2008, and

according to Vera (2017), by the end of 2012 the country had almost completely depleted the

liquid level of its reserves. In addition, the growing external debt service and debt servicing

ratio to total exports have been raising concerns among international investors and limiting

Venezuela’s access to external financing. Moody’s Investors Service downgraded

Venezuela’s debt at the beginning of 2015 from Caa1 to Caa3 (Vera, 2016) and in March

2016 it changed its outlook from stable to negative. While between 2008 and 2012 the debt

service accounted for 20 percent or less of total exports, its value started to increase rapidly

since 2014 as the oil prices plummeted (Vera, 2017). Moreover, since 2010 the state-own oil

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

45002015-02

2015-04

2015-06

2015-08

2015-10

2015-12

2016-02

2016-04

2016-06

2016-08

2016-10

2016-12

2017-02

ParallelDollar SIMADI/DICOM CENCOEX/DIPRO

Page 31: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

28

company PDVSA has been responsible for an important part of the external debt. The

growing debt of the oil company is due to the increasing role of the government’s social

spending programmes. According to Vera (2015), the state-owned oil company was used by

the government to finance social development programs, food imports, infrastructural

programs and also presidential campaigns. Moreover, the government has been using the

PDVSA to monetise its budget deficit by borrowing on the bond market using the oil

company via its American subsidiary Citgo Holding, as the latter has access to lower

borrowing rates (Albert and Jude, 2016). Thus, social spending and low oil prices in recent

years have negatively impacted PDVSA’s finances and contributed to underinvestment,

leading to lower production and further worsening of its debt position. At the same time,

PDVSA benefited from a law passed in 2009 that allowed the central bank to purchase the

bonds issued by the oil company, which enabled it to close its financing gap in the domestic

currency (Vera, 2015). According to Vera (2015), this led to an expansion in the monetary

base (Figure 9) and an increase in the liquidity in the Venezuelan economy.

To summarise, the current skyrocketing inflation rates are a result of the balance of payments

problems, which have been troubling Venezuela since the decline in oil prices at the end of

2014. However, the root cause of the current economic ills lies in the years of inadequate

exchange rate policies, which allowed for the bolivar’s excessive appreciation and in turn

prevented the necessary structural changes that would ensure industrial diversification and

decrease the dependency on oil exports. In the face of growing external constraints, current

account deficits and increasing external debt, the authorities introduced foreign currency

rationing, which led to shortages and output contraction and also put pressure on the black

market for exchange as the devaluation expectations augmented. As a result, the Venezuelan

economy has been experiencing a parallel market devaluation-inflation spiral, which threatens

to turn into hyperinflation as the real value of the monetary base has been declining rapidly

since 2015, suggesting a loss of confidence in the national currency (Figure 9).

Page 32: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

29

Figure 9: Real value of the monetary base (M2), millions of bolivars, 2007-2016

Source: Venezuelan Central Bank (2015) and IMF (2016), author’s calculations

According to our framework, falling confidence in the national currency should lead to

gradual dollarisation. Although Venezuela has had strict foreign exchange controls since

2003, and the parallel market for foreign currency has been illegal since 2010, it is possible to

observe a certain degree of dollarisation of the economy. Given the high rates of inflation, it

can be assumed that the dollar has taken over the function of a store of value. According to

Lampa (2016), between 1997 and 2011, the government and the PDVSA issued $60 billion

worth of dollar-denominated bonds thus incentivising the dollarisation of savings. Moreover,

in the case of certain goods, the dollar serves de facto the role of the unit of account as the

firms that import goods have their sales catalogues denominated in dollars, which means that

local currency prices fluctuate according to the daily black market exchange rate quotations.

Furthermore, the prices in the black market for goods also vary in accordance with the daily

parallel dollar rate. The situation in Venezuela is thus similar to that of Germany during the

1923 hyperinflation; as it was put by Kaldor (1982, p. 61): “[…] in Germany in September

1923, everything from newspapers to railway tickets and to daily wages was ‘indexed’ to the

daily market price of the US dollar. […] If the dollar remained unchanged for a day, prices

and wages … remained stable for the day”. Thus, the only function of money that the bolivar

is currently serving is the medium of payment. Although Venezuela is presently experiencing

rapidly increasing prices and the confidence in the national currency is falling, hyperinflation

0

500000

1000000

1500000

2000000

2500000

3000000

2007-12

2008-05

2008-10

2009-03

2009-08

2010-01

2010-06

2010-11

2011-04

2011-09

2012-02

2012-07

2012-12

2013-05

2013-10

2014-03

2014-08

2015-01

2015-06

2015-11

2016-04

2016-09

Page 33: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

30

is prevented by the institutional settings – exchange controls – which means that a full flight

to foreign currency has not taken place as yet.

4.AssessmentGiven our analysis in section 3, we can propose the following causal sequence:

The above presented sequence for the Venezuelan case is largely in line with the post-

Keynesian theoretical framework presented in section 2, however, certain particularities are

observed. Firstly, no formal indexation mechanisms were introduced in Venezuela and yet the

regime of high inflation was continuously present since the late 1970s. Secondly, the

exchange controls since 2003 led to the growing importance of the parallel exchange market

and since 2012 the changes in the parallel dollar market became more significant than the

changes in the official exchange rate in fuelling the inflation rates as they were reflecting

devaluation expectations. Finally, despite accelerating prices, a full rejection of domestic

currency is not observed (although the confidence in the bolivar is falling) because the

exchange controls are preventing flight to the foreign currency.

Page 34: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

31

5.ConclusionsIn this paper we analysed important economic, but also social and political, events that led to

rapidly accelerating inflation rates in Venezuela and tried to establish whether the current high

inflation can be considered hyperinflation from the post-Keynesian theoretical perspective.

We found that high inflation levels in Venezuela since the 1970s can be explained by the

combination of external bottlenecks and distributive conflicts, which are usually sparked by

currency devaluations. The structural dependency on oil revenues, as a source of foreign

currency necessary for imports of intermediate inputs and capital goods for production (as

well as consumption goods), meant that Venezuela has been experiencing accelerating prices

every time production was constrained by the insufficiency of foreign currency and the BOP

constraint was hit. This in turn induced devaluation pressures and led to prices hikes (due to

higher costs), which fuelled the inflation further as workers opposed to falling purchasing

power and demanded higher nominal wages, inciting a devaluation-inflation spiral. While this

dynamic has been present since the 1970s, what sparked the most recent inflationary episode

was the dramatic increase in the parallel exchange rate at the end of 2012, driven by the

devaluation expectations, which eventually determined the devaluations of the official

exchange rate. In addition, an external shock coming from a massive fall in oil prices at the

end of 2014 worsened the external position and fuelled further devaluation expectations,

leading to a rapid increase in the value of the black market rate for dollar. This in turn has

translated into accelerating rates of inflation as the authorities reduced the provision of foreign

currency.

While the confidence in the bolivar has been markedly decreasing since mid-2015, the

currency substitution is prevented by the exchange controls. Although savings are held in

dollars, and for certain goods and black market goods the dollar is used as the unit of account,

the payments are still done in the local currency. Thus, while we can say that to a certain

degree there is a flight to foreign currency, which is a defining feature of hyperinflation, it is

evident that the domestic currency has not been completely rejected. The particularity of

Venezuela’s exchange policy means that classifying the current period of rapidly accelerating

inflation rates as hyperinflation from the post-Keynesian perspective remains ambiguous, as

exchange controls prevent the full substitution of the bolivar with the US dollar. If the

government decides to remove the currency controls or/and let the official exchange rate float,

we could expect a run to the foreign currency and a full substitution of the domestic currency

with the dollar.

Page 35: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

32

ReferencesAlbert, M., and Jude, C. (2016): “Venezuela: l’insoutenabilité du modèle de croissance, source

de tous les risques”, Revue d'économie financière, (4), 201-222.

Aporrea (2013) : “Presidenta del BCV: Parte de los $59.000 milliones entregados en 2012 fueron a “emrepsas de maletin” ”, ”, accessed on 25.05.17, available at https://www.aporrea.org/actualidad/n229466.html

Banco Central de Venezuela (BCV) (2013): Informe Económico 2012, Banco Central de Venezuela: Caracas.

Bértola, L., and Ocampo, J. A. (2012): The economic development of Latin America since independence, Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Blecker, R. (2011): “Open economy models of distribution and growth” in E. Hein and E. Stockhammer (eds.), Modern Guide to Keynesian Economics and Economic Policies, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, pp. 215-39.

Bresser-Pereira, L. C. (2012): “Structuralist macroeconomics and the new developmentalism” Revista de Economia Política, 32(3), 347-366.

Bresser-Pereira, L. C., Oreiro, J. L. and Marconi, N. (2014): “A Theoretical Framework For A Structuralist Development Macroeconomics”. Proceedings of the 41th Brazilian Economics Meeting - Brazilian Association of Graduate Programs in Economics.

Cagan, P. (1956): “The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation” in M. Friedman (ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, University of Chicago Press: Chicago, pp. 25–117.

Câmara, A., and Vernengo, M. (2001): “The German Balance of Payment School and the Latin American Neo-Structuralists” in L.P. Rochon and M. Vernengo (eds.), Credit, Interest Rates and the Open Economy, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, pp. 143–159.

Carvalho, F.J. (1993) “Strato-Inflation and High Inflation: The Brazilian Experience”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 17 (1), pp. 63–78.

Cassetti, M. (2003): “Bargaining Power, Effective Demand and Technical Progress: a Kaleckian Model of Growth”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27, 449-464.

Charles, S. and Marie, J. (2016): “Hyperinflation in a small open economy with a fixed exchange rate: A post Keynesian view”, Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, 39(3), 1-26.

Charles, S. and Marie, J. (2017): “Bulgaria’s Hyperinflation in 1997: Transition, Banking Fragility, and Foreign Exchange”, Post-Communist Economies (forthcoming)

Diamand, M. (1978): “Towards a change in the economic paradigm through the experience of developing countries”, Journal of Development Economics, 5(1), 19-53.

Page 36: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

33

Di John, J. (2005): “The political economy of anti-politics and social polarisation in Venezuela 1998-2004”, Working Paper no. 76, Crisis States Research Centre, London School of Economics.

Frenkel, R. (1979): “Decisiones de precio en alta inflación.” Desarrollo Económico, 19 (75), 291–330.

Guerra, J. (2002): Estudios sobre la inflación en Venezuela. Banco Central de Venezuela: Caracas.

Gutiérrez, L. H., and Labarca, N. (2003): “Determinantes de la inversión privada en Venezuela: Un análisis econométrico para el periodo 1950-2001”, Revista Tendencias, 4(2).

Hausmann, R., and Rodríguez, F. R. (2014): Venezuela Before Chávez: Anatomy of an Economic Collapse, The Pennsylvania State University Press: University Park, Pennsylvania.

Kaldor, N. (1982): The Scourge of Monetarism, Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Kalecki, M. (1962): “A Model of Hyperinflation”, Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies, 30, 275–281.

Kelly, J., and Palma, P. A. (2004): “The syndrome of economic decline and the quest for change” in J. L. McCoy, and D. J. Myers (eds.) The Unraveling of Representative Democracy in Venezuela, Johns Hopkins University Press: Baltimore, pp. 202-230.

Lampa, R. (2016): “Crisis in Venezuela, or the Bolivarian Dilemma: To Revolutionize or to Perish? A Kaleckian Interpretation”, Review of Radical Political Economics, 1-21.

Lander, E. (1996): “The impact of neoliberal adjustment in Venezuela, 1989-1993”, Latin American Perspectives, 23(3), 50-73.

Lander, E. (2006): Neoliberalismo, sociedad civil y democracia: ensayos sobre América Latina y Venezuela, Universidad Central de Venezuela Consejo de Desarollo Cientifico y Humanistico: Caracas.

Lavoie, M. (2014): Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham.

Manzano, O. (2014): “Venezuela After a Century of Oil Exploitation” in R. Hausmann and F.R. Rodriguez (eds.) in Venezuela Before Chávez: Anatomy of an Economic Collapse, The Pennsylvania State University Press: University Park, Pennsylvania, pp. 51-90.

Marie, J. (2014): “Hyperinflation argentine de 1989 une interprétation post-keynésienne”, Revue de la régulation [Online], 15, accessed on 18.10.16, available at: http://regulation.revues.org/10794

Orléan, A. (2007): “Crise de la souveraineté et crise de la monnaie: l’hyperinflation allemande des années 1920”, in B. Théret (ed.) La monnaie dévoilée par ses crises, Éditions de l’EHESS : Paris, pp. 187-229.

Page 37: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

34

Ortiz, I. (1987): “Determinantes de la inflación en Venezuela: 1960–1980”, Economía, 12 (1), 67-106.

Palma, P. A. (2008): “La política cambiaria en Venezuela”, in Veinticinco Años de Pensamiento Económico Venezolano, Academia Nacional de Ciencias Económicas: Caracas, pp. 463-532.

Palma, P. A. (2011): “Riesgos y consecuencias de las economías rentistas: El caso de Venezuela”, Problemas del desarrollo, 42(165), 35-59.

Palma, P. A. (2016) : "LA INFLACIÓN EN VENEZUELA: SUS CAUSAS Y CORRECCIÓN." Debates IESA 21, no. 1:10-14. Business Source Complete, EBSCOhost (accessed March 28, 2017).

Portillo, S. (2004): Guía rápida de la política económica en Venezuela: 1974-2003, Departamento de Modelos Económicos, Banco Central de Venezuela: Caracas.

Puente, M. J., Gómez, P., and Vera L.(2010) : "LA PRODUCTIVIDAD PERDIDA." Debates IESA 15, no. 1: 66-69. Business Source Complete, EBSCOhost (accessed March 28, 2017).

Rowthorn, R. (1977): “Conflict, Inflation and Money”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1, 215-229.

Setterfield, M. (2007): “The Rise, Decline and Rise of Incomes Policies in the US during the Post-War Era: an Institutional-Analytical Explanation of Inflation and the Functional Distribution of Income”, Journal of Institutional Economics, 3,127-146.

Susjan, A., and Lah, M. (1997): “Inflation in the Transition Economies: the post-Keynesian view”, Review of Political Economy, 9(4), 381-393.

The Economist (2014): “Venezuela’s labour market: Labour’s lost love”, accessed on 25.05.17, available at: http://www.economist.com/news/americas/21594997-regime-has-contrived-make-both-bosses-and-workers-unhappy-labours-love-lost

Thirlwall, A. P. (1979): “The balance of payments constraint as an explanation of the international growth rate differences”, PSL Quarterly Review, 32(128).

Vera, L. (2009): “Cambio estructural, desindustrialización y pérdidas de productividad: evidencia para Venezuela”, Revista Cuadernos del Cendes, ańo 26 (71), 89-115.

Vera, L. (2011): “Paradojas de la desindustrialización¿ Hay evidencia de la Tercera Ley de Kaldor para Venezuela?”, Nueva Economía, 33, 89-107.

Vera, L. (2015): Venezuela 1999–2014: Macro-Policy, Oil Governance and Economic Performance, Comparative Economic Studies, 57(3), 539-568.

Vera, L. (2017): “In search of stabilization and recovery: macro policy and reforms in Venezuela, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 1-18

Page 38: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

35

Weisbrot, M., and Sandoval, L.(2007): “The Venezuelan economy in the Chávez years”, Center for Economic and Policy Research, July 2007.

Page 39: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

36

DataSourcesDataStream (2017): Thomson Reuters Datastream [Online] (Accessed: March 2017)

Dollar Today (2017): Histórico Dólar paralelo en Venezuela (Accessed: March 2017), available at: https://dolartoday.com/historico-dolar/

Economic Commission for Latin America and Caribbean (ECLAC) (2016): CEPALSTAT (Accessed: March 2017), available at: http://estadisticas.cepal.org/cepalstat/WEB_CEPALSTAT/estadisticasIndicadores.asp?idioma=i

International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2016): World Economic Outlook Database October 2016 Edition, (Accessed: March 2017), available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2017/01/weodata/index.aspx

Ministry of Energy and Petroleum (2017): Precios del Petróleo 1998-2017, (Accessed: March 2017), available at: http://www.mpetromin.gob.ve/portalmenpet/secciones.php?option=view&idS=45

United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) (2016) : UNCTADStat (Accessed: March 2017), available at: http://unctadstat.unctad.org/wds/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=16421

Venezuelan Central Bank (2015): Banco Central de Venezuela: Informacion Estadistica, (Accessed: March 2017), available at: http://www.bcv.org.ve/c2/indicadores.asp

Venezuelan Central Bank (2017): Banco Central de Venezuela: Tipos de Cambio de Referencia, (Accessed: March 2017) available at: http://www.bcv.org.ve/cuadros/2/212a.asp?id=64

Page 40: Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a ... · Inflation and hyperinflation in Venezuela (1970s-2016) – a post-Keynesian interpretation* Marta Kulesza Abstract

Imprint Editors: Sigrid Betzelt Trevor Evans Eckhard Hein Hansjörg Herr Birgit Mahnkopf Christina Teipen Achim Truger Markus Wissen ISSN 1869-6406 Printed by HWR Berlin Berlin October 2017