Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    1/23

    Asymmetric Information

    Dr. Katherine Sauer

    Metropolitan State College of Denver

    Health Economics

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    2/23

    Overview:

    I. Asymmetric Information

    II. Health Insurance and the Lemons Principle

    III. The Agency Relationship

    IV. Consumer Information, Prices, and Quality

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    3/23

    I. Asymmetric Information

    A. Extent of Information Problems in the Health Sector

    Certainly information gaps and asymmetries exist in thehealth sector.

    They are perhaps more serious for health care than for

    other goods that are important in household budgets.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    4/23

    Information gaps do not necessarily preclude thepossibility of having a high degree of competition.

    In particular, mechanisms to deal with information

    gaps should not be overlooked.

    These mechanisms include licensure, certification,

    accreditation, threat of malpractice suits, the physician-

    patient relationship, ethical constraints, and the

    presence of informed consumers.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    5/23

    B. The Lemons Principle

    Nobel Laureate George Akerlof (1970) is often credited

    with introducing the idea of asymmetric information

    through an analysis of the used-car market.

    First, it tells us much about adverse selection and the

    potential unraveling of health insurance markets.

    Second, Akerlofs example leads right into the issue ofagency.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    6/23

    When potential buyers know only the average quality of

    used cars, then market prices will tend to be lower than thetrue value of the top-quality cars.

    Owners of the top-quality cars will tend to withhold their

    cars from sale.

    In a sense, the good cars are driven out of the market by

    the lemons.

    Under what has become known as the Lemons Principle,

    the bad drives out the good until no market is left.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    7/23

    II. Health Insurance and the Lemons Principle

    Adverse selection applies to markets involving health

    insurance and to analyses of the relative merits of

    alternative health care provider arrangements.

    Information asymmetry will likely occur because thepotential insureds know more about their expected

    health expenditures in the coming period than does the

    insurance company.

    In this market, the higher health risks tend to drive out

    the lower health risk people, and a functioning market

    may even fail to appear at all for some otherwise-

    insurable health care risks.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    8/23

    A. Inefficiencies of Adverse Selection

    If the lower risks are grouped with higher risks and allpay the same premium, the lower risks face an

    unfavorable rate and will tend to underinsure.

    They sustain a welfare loss by not being able to purchaseinsurance at rates appropriate to their risk.

    Conversely, the higher risks will face a favorable

    premium and therefore overinsure (insure against risksthat they would not otherwise insure against).

    This, too, is inefficient.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    9/23

    B. Evidence of Adverse Selection

    Evidence of adverse selection has been found in

    markets for supplemental Medicare insurance (Wolfe

    and Goddeeris, 1991) and individual (nongroup)

    insurance (Browne and Doerpinghaus, 1993).

    In more recent work with a sample of single, employed

    persons, Cardon and Hendel (2001) found that those

    who were insured spent about 50 percent more onhealth care than the uninsured.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    10/23

    C. Experience Rating and Adverse Selection

    Group insurance can be a more useful mechanism to

    reduce adverse selection.

    Group plans enable insurers to implement experiencerating, a practice where premiums are based on the past

    experience of the group, or other risk-rating systems to

    project expenditures.

    Because employees usually have limited choices both

    within and among plans, they cannot fully capitalize on

    their information advantage.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    11/23

    III. The Agency Relationship

    An agency relationship is formed whenever aprincipal

    delegates decision making authority to another party, the

    agent.

    In the physician-patient relationship, the patient

    (principal) delegates authority to the physician (agent),

    who in many cases also will be the provider of the

    recommended services.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    12/23

    The perfect agent physician is one who chooses as the

    patients themselves would choose if only the patients

    possessed the information that the physician does.

    The problem for the principal is to determine and ensurethat the agent is acting in the principals best interests.

    Unfortunately, the interests may diverge, and it may be

    difficult to introduce arrangements or contracts thateliminate conflicts of interest.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    13/23

    IV. Consumer information, prices and quality

    A. Consumer Information and Prices

    Satterthwaite (1979) and Pauly and Satterthwaite (1981)

    introduced one of the most novel approaches to handle

    issues involving consumer information and competition.

    -identify primary medical care as a reputation

    gooda good for which consumers rely on the

    information provided by friends, neighbors, andothers to select from the various services available

    in the market

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    14/23

    Physicians are not identical and do not offer identical

    services.

    Because of this product differentiation, the market can be

    characterized as monopolistically competitive.

    Under these conditions, the authors show that an increase

    in the number of providers can increase prices.

    The economic idea is that reduced information tends togive each firm some additional monopoly power.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    15/23

    B. The Role of Informed Buyers

    The degree to which imperfect price information

    contributes to monopoly power should not be

    overemphasized.

    A growing body of literature shows that it is sufficient

    to have enough buyers who are sensitive to price

    differentials to exert discipline over the marketplace.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    16/23

    C. Price Dispersion

    Juba (1979) found that the variations in physician fees

    appear to be larger than those found in other relatively

    competitive markets.

    It is not clear, though, that variations in effective

    transactions pricing resulting from insurance agreements

    lie outside of competitive norms.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    17/23

    D. Consumer Information and Quality

    Consider the consumers direct role: that the physicianpatient relationship enables patients to monitor providers

    and encourages physicians to make appropriate referrals.

    To the extent that many specialists rely on referredpatients, these specialists would seem to have incentives

    to maintain quality.

    Are they also rewarded with higher prices for higher-quality services?

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    18/23

    Haas-Wilson study:

    The evidence shows that patients rely on informed

    sources (agents) for information and that higher quality,as measured by informed referrals, is rewarded by higher

    fees.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    19/23

    E. Other Quality Indicators

    The National Committee for Quality Assurance(NCQA), a private accreditation body for HMOs,

    issues report cards based on about 50 standardized

    measures of a plans performance (e.g. childhood

    immunization rates, breast cancer screenings).

    A key assumption behind efforts like this is that

    information about quality will, like price information,help discipline providers through patient choices.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    20/23

    Evidence:

    Initial evidence on the intended effects of planperformance ratings brings the report card strategy

    into question.

    Tumlinson et al. (1997) found that independent planratings are relatively unimportant to consumer

    choices.

    Chernew and Scanlon (1998) confirm thatemployees do not appear to respond strongly to plan

    performance measures, even when the labeling and

    dissemination were intended to facilitate their use.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    21/23

    Scanlon et al (2002) examined a flexible benefits

    system introduced by General Motors in 1996 and 1997and found that plans with many above-average ratings

    were not much more successful in attracting enrollees

    relative to plans with many average ratings.

    Together with other results on plan switching

    (Beaulieu, 2002), we can conclude that the provision of

    quality information does influence consumers,

    particularly when the quality ratings are negative.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    22/23

    Final Thoughts:

    There is little doubt that information gaps, asymmetric

    information, and agency problems are prevalent in

    providerpatient transactions.

    Although there is a potential lack of competition, even

    wide information gaps do not necessarily lead to

    market failure.

  • 8/3/2019 Health Economics- Lecture Ch10

    23/23

    Discussion Questions:

    1. Various commentators have suggested that only 15 to

    20 percent of all health care services have been subject

    to rigorous, controlled investigation (evidence-based

    medicine). If this is true, what are some implications for

    efficiency of health care delivery?

    2. According to clinical research, nearly half of the care

    provided in the US falls short of the recommended

    protocols. How do imperfect and asymmetric

    information contribute to this phenomenon. How can

    health plans or markets be reformed to reduce the quality

    gap?