Economia Política - Cap 8

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    1/9

    INTRODUCTION TO CONTEST THEORY

    1 Definition

    A contest describes a situation where two or more agents ("con-

    testants") spend resources in order to obtain a certain desirable out-

    come ("win a prize").

    Formally, a contest can be characterised by the following elements:

    A set of contestantsN

    = {1,...,n

    } A prize B to be allocated among the contestants

    Contestant is valuation of the prize: vi (B)

    Each contestant i N can make an effort xi, at a cost Ci (xi)

    Notice that a lower valuation of the prize is equivalent to

    having a higher cost of making the effort, and vice versa

    If effort is measured in monetary units, then Ci (xi) = xi

    The probability that contestant i wins the prize is given by the

    contest success function pi = pi (x1,...,xn) Thus, contestant i has an ex ante expected payoff of

    i (x1,...,xn) = pi (x1,...,xn) vi (B) Ci (xi) . (1)

    2 Examples

    An illustrative specific example:

    a certain number of cities competing for becoming the location

    of the next Olympic Games

    each city spends money on architects, marketing agencies, lobby-

    ing, etc, in order to "improve" its proposal, increasing the prob-

    ability of being chosen

    1

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    2/9

    General political economy examples:

    political lobbying

    rent-seeking

    beauty contests (e.g., the Olympic Games example)

    political campaigning

    bribery

    Other examples:

    promotional (advertising) competition

    litigation

    internal labour market tournaments (promotion contests)

    R&D contests

    military conflict

    sports

    3 Fully discriminatory contests

    First-price all-pay auction

    The contestant who expend the highest effort in the contest, wins the

    prize for sure

    More relevant for cases where

    contest effort translates deterministically into some observable

    quality or quantity variable for each contestant

    the allocation of the contested prize is made on the basis of a

    comparison of the value of this variable across the different con-

    testants

    Assume two contestants: 1 and 2

    2

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    3/9

    Their valuations of the prize are given by v1 v2 > 0.

    The effort cost function is C(xi) = xi, i = 1, 2.

    The contest success function for contestant 1 is

    p1 =

    1 if x1 > x21

    2if x1 = x2

    0 if x1 < x2

    , (2)

    while the contest success function for contestant 2 is p2 = 1p1.

    The players choose their efforts, xi 0, simultaneously to max-

    imise expected profi

    ts, given by (1).

    This game has no Nash equilibrium in pure strategies

    Mixed strategy equilibrium:

    F1 (x1) =

    (x1v

    f or x1 [0, v2]

    1 f or x1 > v2(3)

    and

    F2 (x2) = ( 1 v2

    v1+ x2

    v1f or x2 [0, v2]

    1 f or x2 > v2, (4)

    where Fi (xi) is the cumulative distribution function for the effort

    choice of contestant i.

    Expected payoffs in equilibrium are

    E(1) = v1 v2

    and

    E(2) = 0.

    Expected efforts in equilibrium are

    E(x1) =v2

    2

    3

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    4/9

    and

    E(x2) = (v2)

    2

    2v1.

    Notice that the prize will not always be allocated to the contestant

    with the higher valuation.

    If there are more than two players, with

    v1 v2 > v3 v4 ... vn,

    then the unique equilibrium has xi = 0 for i > 2, while contestants 1

    and 2 play (3) and (4), respectively.

    4 Non-discriminatory contests

    In many contests there are some noise and elements of randomness

    In contests with noise, the contestant expending the highest effort does

    not win the contest with certainty

    typical example: political lobbying (rent-seeking) contests

    The most commonly used imperfectly discriminating contest is the

    Tullock contest

    In a standard Tullock contest, the contest success function is given by

    pi (x1,...,xn) =

    (xrinj=1 x

    rj

    if max {x1,...,xn} > 0

    1

    notherwise

    , (5)

    where r > 0.

    The parameter r represents the returns to contest effort (in terms of

    success probability)

    If r < 1, there are decreasing returns to effort

    4

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    5/9

    If r > 1, there are increasing returns to effort

    If r = 1, there are constant returns to effort

    The special case of r = 1 is the "lottery contest".

    the probability of winning corresponds to the relative shares of

    "lottery tickets"

    The Tullock contest success function converges to the contest success

    function of a perfectly discriminatory contest, (2), when r

    4.1 A general example of the Tullock contest

    n players, with valuations v1 v2 ... vn

    Effort is measured in monetary terms: C(xi) = xi

    The contest success function is given by (5)

    Contestants choose effort simultaneously

    Expected profit for contestant i is

    E(i) = xriPn

    j=1 xrj

    vi xi.

    The first-order condition for optimal effort by contestant i is

    E(i)

    xi=

    rxr1iP

    j6=i xrjPn

    j=1 xrj

    2

    vi 1 = 0. (6)

    4.1.1 Special Case 1: Equal valuations (v1 = v2 = ... = vn = v)

    Imposing symmetry, xi = x, in (6) yields

    rxr1 (n 1) xr

    (nxr)2v 1 = 0

    5

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    6/9

    Solving for x yields

    x = (n 1)n2

    rv (7)

    individual contest effort is

    increasing in the valuation of the prize (v)

    increasing in the parameter r

    decreasing in the number of contestants (n)

    Total contest effort is

    X =n

    Xi=1 xi = nx = n 1

    n rv. (8) Total contest effort is increasing in the number of contestants

    Notice that this pure strategy Nash equilibrium exists only if r nn1

    Expected profits in the pure strategy equilibrium are

    E() =1

    nv

    (n 1)

    n2rv

    =v

    n 1

    n 1

    n r

    Expected profits are non-negative only if r n

    n1

    For r > nn1

    , expected profits from playing (7) is negative and

    each contestant can do better by choosing zero effort.

    For r > nn1

    , only mixed strategy equilibria exist.

    Rent dissipation

    Rent dissipation is measured by the ratio of total effort and the

    valuation of the prize: Xv

    In the pure strategy equilibrium, the degree of rent dissipation is given

    byX

    v=

    n 1

    n

    r (0, 1)

    6

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    7/9

    Notice that, since r nn1

    , there is never overdissipation in the pure

    strategy equilibrium.

    The contested rent is fully dissipated only in the extreme case ofr = 1

    and free entry /(n )

    If r < 1, there is always underdissipation of the rent, even with free

    entry of contestants.

    this means that rents survive even under perfect competition from

    an infinite number of potential contestants!

    4.1.2 Special Case 2: Two contestants with unequal valuations

    Setting n = 2, the first-order condition (6) can be rewritten as

    rxr1i xrj

    (xr1

    + xr2

    )2vi = 1; i, j = 1, 2; i 6= j

    Taking the ratio of the two first-order conditions yields

    x1

    v1=

    x2

    v2,

    implying

    x1 x2 (since v1 v2 by assumption).

    The player who value the prize more expends more effort in the contest

    Both players dissipate the same (constant) fraction of their valuations

    in rent-seeking activities, regardless of the parameter r.

    4.1.3 Special Case 3: The lottery contest (r = 1)

    Setting r = 1, the first-order condition (6) reduces toPj6=i xjPnj=1 xj

    2

    vi 1 = 0,

    7

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    8/9

    which can be written as

    (X xi) viX2

    = 1,

    where X =Pn

    j=1 xj is total contest effort.

    Solving for xi yields

    xi = X

    1

    X

    vi

    (9)

    By summing over n, we can derive total contest effort in equilibrium

    X =

    nXi=1

    xi =

    nXi=1

    X1 Xvi = XnXnX

    i=1

    1vi! ,

    which, when solving for X, yields

    X =n 1Pni=1

    1

    vi

    .

    Alternatively, this expression can be written as

    X =

    n 1

    n eVn, (10)

    where eVn = nPni=1 1vi1 is the harmonic mean of the contestantsvaluations.

    Notice from (9) that a contestant will participate in the contest (i.e.,

    choosing xi > 0) if X < vi.

    Total effort is always lower than the valuation of the active player

    with the lowest valuation of the prize.

    In general: More unequal valuations among the contestants will

    reduce total effort

    8

  • 8/14/2019 Economia Poltica - Cap 8

    9/9

    5 Extensions to the standard contest set-up

    Entry fees to participate in the contest

    Multiple prizes

    Budget constraints

    Endogenous prizes

    Contest effort affects the players valuations of the prize

    Delegation

    Sabotage

    Contests for a public good

    Strategic alliances

    6 Contest design

    How should a contest administrator optimally design a contest?

    how many contestants?

    which type of contestants?

    entry fees or not?

    optimal choice of prize

    influence the cost-of-effort for the contestants

    What is the objective function of a contest designer?

    maximise total eff

    ort?

    9